From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Blogger Ref Link http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics
Schools of economic thought describes the variety of approaches in the history of economic thought noteworthy enough to be described as a school of thought. While economists do not always fit into particular schools, particularly in modern times, classifying economists into schools of thought is common. Economic thought may be roughly divided into three phases: premodern (Greco-Roman, Indian, Persian, Islamic, and Imperial Chinese), early modern (mercantilist,physiocrats) and modern (beginning with Adam Smith and classical economics in the late 18th century). Systematic economic theory has been developed mainly since the beginning of what is termed the modern era.
Currently, the great majority of economists follow an approach referred to as mainstream economics (sometimes called 'orthodox economics'). Within the mainstream, distinctions can be made between the Saltwater school (associated withBerkeley, Harvard, MIT, Pennsylvania, Princeton, and Yale), and the more laissez-faire ideas of the Freshwater school (represented by the Chicago school of economics, Carnegie Mellon University, the University of Rochester and theUniversity of Minnesota). Both of these schools of thought are associated with the neoclassical synthesis.
Some influential approaches of the past, such as the historical school of economics and institutional economics, have become defunct or have declined in influence, and are now considered heterodox approaches. Recent heterodox developments include feminist, Green economics, Post-autistic economics, and Thermoeconomics. Heterodox approaches often do not focus on a central rigorous theory but rather embody criticisms of the "mainstream". For instance:
- Feminist economics criticizes the valuation of labor and argues female labor is systemically undervalued
- Green economics criticizes externalized and intangible status of ecosystems and argues to bring them within the tangible measured capital asset model as natural capital
- Post-autistic economics criticizes the focus on formal models at the expense of observation and values, arguing for a return to the moral philosophy in which Adam Smith originally founded this human science.
It may be accordingly easier to describe these as variants of mainstream economic thought rather than as schools in themselves.
Contents
[hide]- 1 Ancient economic thought
- 2 Islamic economics
- 3 Scholasticism
- 4 Mercantilism
- 5 Physiocrats
- 6 Classical political economy
- 7 American (National) School
- 8 French liberal school
- 9 German historical school
- 10 English historical school
- 11 French historical school
- 12 Utopian economics
- 13 Marxian economics
- 14 State socialism
- 15 Ricardian socialism
- 16 Anarchist economics
- 17 Distributism
- 18 Institutional economics
- 19 New institutional economics
- 20 Neoclassical economics
- 21 Lausanne school
- 22 Austrian school
- 23 Stockholm school
- 24 Keynesian economics
- 25 Chicago school
- 26 Carnegie school
- 27 Neo-Ricardianism
- 28 Modern schools
- 29 Current heterodox schools
- 30 Other 20th century schools
- 31 Viewpoints within mainstream economics
- 32 Viewpoints outside economics
- 33 See also
- 34 Notes
- 35 References
- 36 External links
Ancient economic thought[edit]
Main article: Ancient economic thought
- Chanakya (Kautilya)
- Xenophon
- Aristotle
- Qin Shi Huang
- Wang Anshi
Islamic economics[edit]
Main articles: Islamic economic jurisprudence and Islamic economics in the world
Islamic economics is the practice of economics in accordance with Islamic law. The origins can be traced back to the Caliphate,[1] where an early market economyand some of the earliest forms of merchant capitalism took root between the 8th–12th centuries, which some refer to as "Islamic capitalism".[2]
Islamic economics seeks to enforce Islamic regulations not only on personal issues, but to implement broader economic goals and policies of an Islamic society, based on uplifting the deprived masses. It was founded on free and unhindered circulation of wealth so as to handsomely reach even the lowest echelons of society. One distinguishing feature is the tax on wealth (in the form of both Zakat and Jizya), and bans levying taxes on all kinds of trade and transactions (Income/Sales/Excise/Import/Export duties etc.). Another distinguishing feature is prohibition of interest in the form of excess charged while trading in money. Its pronouncement on use of paper currency also stands out. Though promissory notes are recognized, they must be fully backed by reserves. Fractional-reserve banking is disallowed as a form of breach of trust.
It saw innovations such as trading companies, big businesses, contracts, bills of exchange, long-distance international trade, the first forms of partnership(mufawada) such as limited partnerships (mudaraba), and the earliest forms of credit, debt, profit, loss, capital (al-mal), capital accumulation (nama al-mal),[3]circulating capital, capital expenditure, revenue, cheques, promissory notes,[4] trusts (see Waqf), startup companies,[5] savings accounts, transactional accounts,pawning, loaning, exchange rates, bankers, money changers, ledgers, deposits, assignments, the double-entry bookkeeping system,[6] lawsuits,[7] and agencyinstitution.[8][9]
This school has seen a revived interest in development and understanding since the later part of 20th century.
- Muhammad
- Abu Hanifa an-Nu‘man
- Abu Yusuf
- Al-Farabi (Alpharabius)
- Shams al-Mo'ali Abol-hasan Ghaboos ibn Wushmgir (Qabus)
- Ibn Sina (Avicenna)
- Ibn Miskawayh
- Al-Ghazali (Algazel)
- Al-Mawardi
- Nasīr al-Dīn al-Tūsī (Tusi)
- Ibn Taymiyyah
- Ibn Khaldun
- Al-Maqrizi
Scholasticism[edit]
Main article: Scholasticism
Mercantilism[edit]
Main article: Mercantilism
Economic policy in Europe during the late Middle Ages and early Renaissance treated economic activity as a good which was to be taxed to raise revenues for thenobility and the church. Economic exchanges were regulated by feudal rights, such as the right to collect a toll or hold a faire, as well as guild restrictions and religious restrictions on lending. Economic policy, such as it was, was designed to encourage trade through a particular area. Because of the importance of social class, sumptuary laws were enacted, regulating dress and housing, including allowable styles, materials and frequency of purchase for different classes. Niccolò Machiavelli in his book The Prince was one of the first authors to theorize economic policy in the form of advice. He did so by stating that princes and republicsshould limit their expenditures, and prevent either the wealthy or the populace from despoiling the other. In this way a state would be seen as "generous" because it was not a heavy burden on its citizens.
Physiocrats[edit]
This section cites its sources but does not provide page references. (September 2010) |
Main article: Physiocrats
In his Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Murray Rothbard argued that the modern history of economics should properly begin with the physiocrats rather than with Adam Smith.
Classical political economy[edit]
Main article: Classical economics
Classical economics, also called classical political economy, was the original form of mainstream economics of the 18th and 19th centuries. Classical economics focuses on the tendency of markets to move to equilibrium and on objective theories of value. Neo-classical economics differs from classical economics primarily in being utilitarian in its value theory and using marginal theory as the basis of its models and equations. Marxian economics also descends from classical theory.Anders Chydenius (1729–1803) was the leading classical liberal of Nordic history. A Finnish priest and member of parliament, he published a book called The National Gain in 1765, in which he proposes ideas of freedom of trade and industry and explores the relationship between economy and society and lays out the principles of liberalism, all of this eleven years before Adam Smith published a similar and more comprehensive book, The Wealth of Nations. According to Chydenius, democracy, equality and a respect for human rights were the only way towards progress and happiness for the whole of society.
- Francis Hutcheson
- Bernard de Mandeville
- David Hume
- Adam Smith
- Thomas Malthus
- James Mill
- Francis Place
- David Ricardo
- Henry Thornton
- John Ramsay McCulloch
- James Maitland, 8th Earl of Lauderdale
- Jeremy Bentham
- Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi
- Johann Heinrich von Thünen
- John Stuart Mill
- Karl Marx
- Henry George
- Nassau William Senior
- Edward Gibbon Wakefield
- John Rae
- Thomas Tooke
- Robert Torrens
American (National) School[edit]
Main article: American School (economics)
The American School owes its origin to the writings and economic policies of Alexander Hamilton, the first Treasury Secretary of the United States. It emphasized hightariffs on imports to help develop the fledgling American manufacturing base and to finance infrastructure projects, as well as National Banking, Public Credit, andgovernment investment into advanced scientific and technological research and development. Friedrich List, one of the most famous proponents of the economic system, named it the National System, and was the main impetus behind the development of the German Zollverein and the economic policies of Germany under Chancellor Otto Von Bismarck beginning in 1879.
French liberal school[edit]
Main article: French Liberal School
German historical school[edit]
Main article: Historical school of economics
The Historical school of economics was an approach to academic economics and to public administration that emerged in 19th century in Germany, and held sway there until well into the 20th century. The Historical school held that history was the key source of knowledge about human actions and economic matters, since economics was culture-specific, and hence not generalizable over space and time. The School rejected the universal validity of economic theorems. They saw economics as resulting from careful empirical and historical analysis instead of from logic and mathematics. The School preferred historical, political, and social studies to self-referential mathematical modelling. Most members of the school were also Kathedersozialisten, i.e. concerned with social reform and improved conditions for the common man during a period of heavy industrialization. The Historical School can be divided into three tendencies: the Older, led by Wilhelm Roscher, Karl Knies, and Bruno Hildebrand; the Younger, led by Gustav von Schmoller, and also including Étienne Laspeyres, Karl Bücher, Adolph Wagner, and to some extent Lujo Brentano; the Youngest, led by Werner Sombart and including, to a very large extent, Max Weber.
Predecessors included Friedrich List. The Historical school largely controlled appointments to Chairs of Economics in German universities, as many of the advisors of Friedrich Althoff, head of the university department in the Prussian Ministry of Education 1882-1907, had studied under members of the School. Moreover, Prussia was the intellectual powerhouse of Germany and so dominated academia, not only in central Europe, but also in the United States until about 1900, because the American economics profession was led by holders of German Ph.Ds. The Historical school was involved in the Methodenstreit ("strife over method") with the Austrian School, whose orientation was more theoretical and a prioristic. In English speaking countries, the Historical school is perhaps the least known and least understood approach to the study of economics, because it differs radically from the now-dominant Anglo-American analytical point of view. Yet the Historical school forms the basis—both in theory and in practice—of the social market economy, for many decades the dominant economic paradigm in most countries of continental Europe. The Historical school is also a source of Joseph Schumpeter's dynamic, change-oriented, and innovation-based economics. Although his writings could be critical of the School, Schumpeter's work on the role of innovation and entrepreneurship can be seen as a continuation of ideas originated by the Historical School, especially the work of von Schmoller and Sombart.
English historical school[edit]
Main article: English historical school of economics
Although not nearly as famous as its German counterpart, there was also an English Historical School, whose figures included William Whewell, Richard Jones,Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie, Walter Bagehot, Thorold Rogers, Arnold Toynbee, William Cunningham, and William Ashley. It was this school that heavily critiqued the deductive approach of the classical economists, especially the writings of David Ricardo. This school revered the inductive process and called for the merging of historical fact with those of the present period.
French historical school[edit]
Utopian economics[edit]
Marxian economics[edit]
Main article: Marxian economics
Marxian economics descended from the work of Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels. This school focuses on the labor theory of value and what Marx considered to be the exploitation of labour by capital. Thus, in Marxian economics, the labour theory of value is a method for measuring the exploitation of labour in a capitalist society, rather than simply a theory of price.[10][11]
State socialism[edit]
Main article: Socialist economics
Ricardian socialism[edit]
Main article: Ricardian socialism
Anarchist economics[edit]
Main article: Anarchist economics
Anarchist economics is a set of theories which seeks to outline modes of production and exchange that are not governed by coercive social institutions. Mutualistsadvocate market socialism, collectivist anarchists workers cooperatives and salaries based on the amount of time contributed to production, anarcho-communistsadvocate a direct transition from capitalism to libertarian communism and a gift economy with direct communal democracy and anarcho-syndicalists worker's direct action and the general strike.
Distributism[edit]
Main article: Distributism
Distributism is an economic philosophy that was originally formulated in the late 19th century and early 20th century by Catholic thinkers to reflect the teachings of Pope Leo XIII's encyclical Rerum Novarum, and Pope Pius's XI encyclical Quadragesimo Anno. It seeks to pursue a third way between capitalism and socialism, desiring to order society according to Christian principles of justice while still preserving private property.
Institutional economics[edit]
Main article: Institutional economics
New institutional economics[edit]
Main article: New institutional economics
Neoclassical economics[edit]
Main article: Neoclassical economics
Neoclassical economics is the dominant form of economics used today and has the highest amount of adherents among economists. It is often referred to by its critics as Orthodox Economics. The more specific definition this approach implies was captured by Lionel Robbins in a 1932 essay: "the science which studies human behavior as a relation between scarce means having alternative uses." The definition of scarcity is that available resources are insufficient to satisfy all wants and needs; if there is no scarcity and no alternative uses of available resources, then there is no economic problem.
Lausanne school[edit]
Main article: Lausanne School
Austrian school[edit]
Main article: Austrian School
Austrian economists advocate methodological individualism in interpreting economic developments, the subjective theory of value, that money is non-neutral, and emphasize the organizing power of the price mechanism (see economic calculation debate).[12] Austrian economists generally advocate a laissez faire approach to the economy.[13]
Stockholm school[edit]
Main article: Stockholm School
Keynesian economics[edit]
Main articles: Keynesian economics, Post-Keynesian economics, Neo-Keynesian economics and New Keynesian economics
Keynesian economics has developed from the work of John Maynard Keynes and focused on macroeconomics in the short-run, particularly the rigidities caused when prices are fixed. It has two successors. Post-Keynesian economics is an alternative school—one of the successors to the Keynesian tradition with a focus onmacroeconomics. They concentrate on macroeconomic rigidities and adjustment processes, and research micro foundations for their models based on real-life practices rather than simple optimizing models. Generally associated with Cambridge, England and the work of Joan Robinson (see Post-Keynesian economics).New-Keynesian economics is the other school associated with developments in the Keynesian fashion. These researchers tend to share with other Neoclassicaleconomists the emphasis on models based on micro foundations and optimizing behavior, but focus more narrowly on standard Keynesian themes such as price and wage rigidity. These are usually made to be endogenous features of these models, rather than simply assumed as in older style Keynesian ones (see New-Keynesian economics).
Chicago school[edit]
Main article: Chicago school of economics
Carnegie school[edit]
Main article: Carnegie School
Neo-Ricardianism[edit]
Main article: Neo-Ricardianism
Modern schools[edit]
- Mainstream economics is a term used to distinguish economics in general from heterodox approaches and schools within economics. It begins with the premise that resources are scarce and that it is necessary to choose between competing alternatives. That is, economics deals with tradeoffs. With scarcity, choosing one alternative implies forgoing another alternative—the opportunity cost. The opportunity cost expresses an implicit relationship between competing alternatives. Such costs, considered as prices in a market economy, are used for analysis of economic efficiency or for predicting responses to disturbances in a market. In aplanned economy comparable shadow price relations must be satisfied for the efficient use of resources, as first demonstrated by the Italian economist Enrico Barone. Economists represent incentives and costs as playing a pervasive role in shaping decision making. An immediate example of this is the consumer theoryof individual demand, which isolates how prices (as costs) and income affect quantity demanded. Modern mainstream economics builds primarily on neoclassical economics, which began to develop in the late 19th century. Mainstream economics also acknowledges the existence of market failure and insights fromKeynesian economics. It uses models of economic growth for analyzing long-run variables affecting national income. It employs game theory for modeling market or non-market behavior. Some important insights on collective behavior (for example, emergence of organizations) have been incorporated through the new institutional economics. A definition that captures much of modern economics is that of Lionel Robbins in a 1932 essay: "the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses." Scarcity means that available resources are insufficient to satisfy all wants and needs. Absent scarcity and alternative uses of available resources, there is no economic problem. The subject thus defined involves the study ofchoice, as affected by incentives and resources. Economics generally is the study of how people allocate scarce resources among alternative uses.
- Heterodox economics: Some schools of thought at variance with the microeconomic formalism of neoclassical economics are listed here, and include:institutional economics, Marxian economics, feminist economics, socialist economics, binary economics, ecological economics, bioeconomics andthermoeconomics.
Current heterodox schools[edit]
In the late 19th century, a number of heterodox schools contended with the neoclassical school that arose following the marginal revolution. Most survive to the present day as self-consciously dissident schools, but with greatly diminished size and influence relative to mainstream economics. The most significant areInstitutional economics, Marxian economics and the Austrian School.
The development of Keynesian economics was a substantial challenge to the dominant neoclassical school of economics. Keynesian views eventually entered the mainstream as a result of the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis developed by John Hicks. The rise of Keynesianism, and its incorporation into mainstream economics, reduced the appeal of heterodox schools. However, advocates of a more fundamental critique of orthodox economics formed a school of Post-Keynesian economics.
More recent heterodox developments include evolutionary economics (though this term is also used to describe institutional economics), feminist, Green economics,Post-autistic economics, and Thermoeconomics
Most heterodox views are critical of capitalism. The most notable exception is Austrian economics.
Georgescu-Roegen reintroduced into economics, the concept of entropy from thermodynamics (as distinguished from what, in his view, is the mechanistic foundation of neoclassical economics drawn from Newtonian physics) and did foundational work which later developed into evolutionary economics. His work contributed significantly to thermoeconomics and to ecological economics.[14][15][16][17][18]
Other 20th century schools[edit]
Notable schools or trends of thought referring to a particular style of economics advocated by and disseminated from well-defined groups of academicians that have become known worldwide, may be generally summarized as follows:
- Austrian School
- Biological economics
- Chicago School
- Constitutional economics
- Ecological economics
- Evolutionary economics
- Freiburg School
- Freiwirtschaft
- Institutional economics
- Keynesian economics
- Marxian (Marxist) and neo-Marxian economics
- Neo-Ricardianism
- New classical macroeconomics
- New Keynesian economics
- Post-Keynesian economics
- Public Choice school
- School of Lausanne
- Stockholm school
In the late 20th century, three of the areas of study which are producing change in economic thinking are: risk-based, rather than price-based models; imperfect economic actors; and treating economics as a biological science, based on evolutionary norms rather than abstract exchange.
The study of risk has been influential, in viewing variations in price over time as more important than actual price. This applies particularly to financial economics, where risk/return tradeoffs are the crucial decisions to be made.
The most important area of growth has been in the study of information and decision. Examples of this school include the work of Joseph Stiglitz. Problems of asymmetric information and moral hazard, both based around information economics, profoundly affect modern economic dilemmas like executive stock options,insurance markets, and Third-World debt relief.
Finally, there are a series of economic ideas rooted in the conception of economics as a branch of biology, including the idea that energy relationships, rather than price relationships, determine economic structure, and the use of fractal geometry to create economic models. (See Energy Economics.) In its infancy is the application of non-linear dynamics to economic theory, as well as the application of evolutionary psychology. So far, the most visible work has been in the area of applying fractals to market analysis, particularly arbitrage. (See Complexity economics.) Another infant branch of economics is neuroeconomics. The latter combinesneuroscience, economics, and psychology to study how we make choices.
Viewpoints within mainstream economics[edit]
Mainstream economics encompasses a wide (but not unbounded) range of views. Politically, most mainstream economists hold views ranging from laissez-faire tomodern liberalism. There are also divergent views on particular issues within economics, such as the effectiveness and desirability of Keynesian macroeconomic policy. Although, historically, few mainstream economists have regarded themselves as members of a "school", many would identify with one or more of neoclassical economics, monetarism, Keynesian economics, new classical economics, Austrian School, or behavioral economics.
Controversies within mainstream economics tend to be stated in terms of:
- the definitions of capital assets including natural capital (ecosystems) or social capital ("goodwill" or "brand value") or talent, and generally what constituteintangibles versus what can be measured
- investment and malinvestment and how the business cycle eradicates the latter leaving the former
- liability and who bears it, for instance the questions of network externalities
- wealth and value and how these affect price, especially of labour and of ecosystems
An example of a "mainstream" economic approach is the Triple Bottom Line accounting methods for cities developed by ICLEI and advocated by the C40organization of the world's 40 largest cities. As this example suggests, a "mainstream" approach is defined by the degree to which it is adopted and advocated, not necessarily its technical rigor.
Viewpoints outside economics[edit]
Other viewpoints on economic issues from outside economics include dependency theory and world systems theory. An example of another economic system which has recently been advocated is the participatory economics model. This uses neither market methods nor centralised methods for allocation, but incorporates many local positive and negative feedback loops in order to respond to the most positive human values. One example of this school of thought is the Post-autistic economics movement.
See also[edit]
- History of economic thought
- Schools of economic thought and methodology JEL: B Subcategories of the JEL classification codes
- Kameralism
- Manchester School
- Birmingham School
Notes[edit]
- ^ The Cambridge economic history of Europe, p. 437. Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-08709-0.
- ^ Subhi Y. Labib (1969), "Capitalism in Medieval Islam", The Journal of Economic History 29 (1), pp. 79–96 [81, 83, 85, 90, 93, 96].
- ^ Jairus Banaji (2007), "Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism",Historical Materialism 15 (1), pp. 47–74, Brill Publishers.
- ^ Robert Sabatino Lopez, Irving Woodworth Raymond, Olivia Remie Constable (2001), Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World: Illustrative Documents,Columbia University Press, ISBN 0-231-12357-4.
- ^ Timur Kuran (2005), "The Absence of the Corporation in Islamic Law: Origins and Persistence", American Journal of Comparative Law 53, pp. 785–834 [798–9].
- ^ Subhi Y. Labib (1969), "Capitalism in Medieval Islam", The Journal of Economic History 29 (1): 79–96 [92–3]
- ^ Ray Spier (2002), "The history of the peer-review process", Trends in Biotechnology 20 (8), p. 357-358 [357].
- ^ Said Amir Arjomand (1999), "The Law, Agency, and Policy in Medieval Islamic Society: Development of the Institutions of Learning from the Tenth to the Fifteenth Century", Comparative Studies in Society and History 41, pp. 263–93.Cambridge University Press.
- ^ Samir Amin (1978), "The Arab Nation: Some Conclusions and Problems",MERIP Reports 68, pp. 3–14 [8, 13].
- ^ Roemer, J.E. (1987). "Marxian Value Analysis". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London and New York: Macmillan and Stockton. pp. v. 3, 383. ISBN 0-333-37235-2.
- ^ Mandel, Ernest (1987). "Marx, Karl Heinrich". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London and New York: Macmillan and Stockton. pp. v. 3, 372, 376. ISBN 0-333-37235-2.
- ^ http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/AustrianSchoolofEconomics.html
- ^ Raico, Ralph (2011). "Austrian Economics and Classical Liberalism".mises.org. Mises Institute. Retrieved 27 July 2011. "despite the particular policy views of its founders ..., Austrianism was perceived as the economics of the free market"
- ^ Cleveland, C. and Ruth, M. 1997. When, where, and by how much do biophysical limits constrain the economic process? A survey of Georgescu-Roegen's contribution to ecological economics. Ecological Economics 22: 203-223.
- ^ Daly, H. 1995. On Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen’s contributions to economics: An obituary essay. Ecological Economics 13: 149-54.
- ^ Mayumi, K. 1995. Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen (1906-1994): an admirable epistemologist. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 6: 115-120.
- ^ Mayumi,K. and Gowdy, J. M. (eds.) 1999. Bioeconomics and Sustainability: Essays in Honor of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
- ^ Mayumi, K. 2001. The Origins of Ecological Economics: The Bioeconomics of Georgescu-Roegen. London: Routledge.
References[edit]
- Spiegel, Henry William. 1991. The Growth of Economic Thought. Durham & London: Duke University Press. ISBN 0-8223-0973-4
- The History of Economic Thought Website at the New School
- John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, ed. (1987). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, Appendix IV, History of Economic Thought and Doctrine, "Schools of Thought," p. 980 (list of 23 schools)
External links[edit]
|
No comments:
Post a Comment