[edit] Network economy
The network economy may be viewed from a number of perspectives: transition from the industrial economy, digital and information infrastructure, global scale, value networks, and intellectual property rights.From a transitional point of view, Malone and Laubacher (1998) indicate that the Information Revolution has changed the nature of business activity. Because information can be shared instantly and inexpensively on a global scale, the value of centralized decision making and expensive bureaucracies is greatly diminished. Brand (1999) points out that commerce is being accelerated by the digital and network revolutions and that the role of commerce is to both exploit and absorb these shocks. Some effort must focus on developing new infrastructure while other activity will emphasize governance and evolving culture. Rifkin (2000) notes that real estate has become a business burden in network-based markets.
From an infrastructure perspective, Tapscott (1996) compares information networks of the new economy to highways and the power grid of the industrial economy. He suggests that no country can succeed without state-of-the-art electronic infrastructure. Schwartz (1999) writes that in the future, large companies will manage their purchasing, invoicing, document exchange, and logistics through global networks that connect a billion computing devices.
At global scales, Tapscott (1996) indicates that companies can provide 24-hour service as customer requests are transferred from one time zone to another without customers being aware that the work is being done on the other side of the world. Boyett and Boyett (2001) point out that the larger the network, the greater its value and desirability. In a networked economy, success begets more success.
Kelly (1998) states that in a network economy, value is created and shared by all members of a network rather than by individual companies and that economies of scale stem from the size of the network - not the enterprise. Yochai Benkler (2006)[1] notes that value measures for social production must take both extrinsic (e.g. monetary) and intrinsic (e.g., personal satisfaction) rewards into account. Similarly, because value flows from connectivity, Boyett and Boyett (2001) point out that an open system is preferable to a closed system because the former typically have more nodes. They also indicate that such networks are blurring the boundaries between a company and its environment.
A network economy raises important issues with respect to intellectual property. Shapiro and Varian (1999) explain that once a first copy of information has been produced, producing additional copies costs virtually nothing. Rifkin (2000) proposes that as markets make way for networks, ownership is being replaced by access rights because ownership becomes increasingly marginal to business success and economic progress.
[edit] See also
- Digital revolution
- Digital economy
- Electronic business
- Electronic commerce
- Information economy
- Information highway
- Information market
- Information Revolution
- information society
- Intellectual property
- Internet economy
- Knowledge economy
- Knowledge market
- Networked information economy
- Social networking
- Social peer-to-peer processes
- Virtual economy
[edit] References
- Boyett, Joseph H. And Jimmie T. Boyett. 2001. The Guru Guide to the Knowledge Economy. John Wiley& Sons. pp. 46, 47
- Brand, Stewart. The Clock of the Long Now. Basic Books. p. 37
- Kelly, Kevin. 1998. New Rules for the Wired Economy. p. 26
- Malone, Thomas W. And Robert J. Laubacher. 1998. The Dawn of the E-Lance Economy, in: Harvard Business Review (Sept. 1998)
- Rifkin, Jeremy. 2000. The Age of Access. Penguin Putnam. p. 4, 5, 35
- Schwartz, Evan I. 1999. Digital Darwinism. Broadway Books. p. 7
- Shapiro, Carl and Hal R. Varian. 1999. Harvard Business School Press. p. 21
- Tapscott, Donald. 1996. The Digital Economy. McGraw-Hill. p. 15, 65
- ^ Benkler, Yochai (2006). Wealth of Networks. Yale University Press.
No comments:
Post a Comment