The Social Credit proposals explained in 10
lessons
Lesson 4: The
solution:
debt-free money issued by society
debt-free money issued by society
The cost of servicing the
public debt increases proportionally to the debt, since it is a percentage of
this same debt. To finance its debt, the Federal Government sells Treasury Bills
and other bonds, most of them being bought by chartered banks.
As regards the sale of
Treasury bonds, the Government is a stupid seller: it does not sell its bonds to
the banks; it gives these bonds away to them, since these bonds cost the banks
nothing: the banks do not lend the money; they create it. Not only do banks get
something for nothing, but they also get interest on it.
On September 30, 1941, a
revealing exchange took place between Mr. Wright Patman, Chairman of the U.S.
House of Representatives Banking and Currency Committee, and Mr. Marriner
Eccles, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board (the central bank of the U.S.A.)
concerning a $2 billion monetary issue which the Bank created:
|
|
Wright Patman
|
Marriner S. Eccles
|
Mr. Patman: "How did you get
the money to buy those $2 billion of Government securities?"
Mr. Eccles: "We created
it."
Mr. Patman: "Out of
what?"
Mr. Eccles: "Out of the
right to issue money, credit."
Mr. Patman: "And there is
nothing behind it, except the Government’s credit?"
Mr. Eccles: "We have the
Government bonds."
Mr. Patman: "That’s right,
the Government’s credit."
This puts us on the right
track for a solution to the debt problem: if these bonds are based on the
Government’s credit, why would the Government have to go through the banks to
use its own credit?
It is not the banker who
gives value to money, but the credit of the Government, of society. The only
thing the banker does in this transaction is to make an entry in a ledger,
writing figures which allow the country to make use of its own production
capacity, its own wealth.
Money is nothing else but
that: a figure — a figure which is a claim on products. Money is only a symbol,
a creation of the law, according to Aristotle’s words. Money is not wealth, but
the symbol that gives rights to wealth. Without products, money is worthless.
So, why pay for figures? Why pay for something which costs nothing to
make?
And since this money is
based on the production capacity of society, this money also belongs to society.
Then, why should society pay the bankers for the use of its own money? Why pay
for the use of our own goods? Why doesn’t the Government issue its own money
directly, without going through the banks?
Graham Towers
|
Even the first Governor of
the Bank of Canada admitted that the Federal Government had the right to issue
its own money. Graham Towers, who was Governor of the Bank from 1935 to 1951,
was asked the following question, before the Canadian Committee on Banking and
Commerce, in the spring of 1939:
Question: "Will you tell me
why a government with the power to create money should give that power away to a
private monopoly and then borrow that which Parliament can create itself, back
at interest, to the point of national bankruptcy?"
Towers’ answer: "Now, if
Parliament wants to change the form of operating the banking system, that is
certainly within the power of Parliament."
|
Thomas
Edison
|
U.S. inventor Thomas Edison
said: "If our nation can issue a
dollar bond, it can issue a dollar bill. The element that makes the bond good,
makes the bill good also. The difference between the bond and the bill is that
the bond lets the money brokers collect twice the amount of the bond and an
additional 20 percent, whereas the currency pays nobody but those who contribute
directly to Muscle Shoals in some useful way...
"It is absurd to say that
our country can issue $30 million in bonds and not $30 million in currency. Both
are promises to pay, but one fattens the usurers and the other helps the people.
If the currency issued by the Government was no good, then the bonds would be no
good either. It is a terrible situation when the Government, to increase the
national wealth, must go into debt and submit to ruinous interest charges at the
hands of men who control the fictitious value of gold."
Here are some questions the
Social Crediters are often asked:
Question: Does the
Government have the power to create money? Would this money be as good as that
of the banks?
Answer: The Government has
indeed the power to create, issue the money of our country, since it is itself,
the Federal Government, that has given this power to the chartered banks. For
the Government to refuse to itself a privilege it has granted to the banks, is
the height of imbecility! Moreover, it is actually the first duty of any
sovereign government to issue its own currency, but all the countries today have
unjustly given up this power to private corporations, the chartered banks. The
first nation that thus surrendered to private corporations its power to create
money was Great Britain, back in 1694. In both Canada and the U.S.A., this right
was surrendered in 1913.
No danger of
inflation
Question: Is there not any
danger that the Government might misuse this power and issue too much money,
which would result in runaway inflation? Is it not preferable for the Government
to leave this power to the bankers, in order to keep it away from the whims of
the politicians?
Answer: The money issued by
the Government would be no more inflationary than the money created by the
banks: it would be the same figures, based on the same production of the
country. The only difference is that the Government would not have to get into
debt, or to pay interest, in order to obtain these figures.
On the contrary, the first
cause of inflation is precisely the money created as a debt by the banks:
inflation means increasing prices. The obligation for the corporations and
governments that are borrowing to bring back to the banks more money than the
banks created, forces the corporations to increase the prices of their products,
and the governments to increase their taxes.
What is the means used by
the present Governor of the Bank of Canada to fight inflation? Precisely what
actually increases it, that is to say, to increase the interest rates! As many
Premiers put it, "It is like trying to extinguish a fire by pouring gasoline
over it."
It is obvious that if the
Canadian Government decided to create or print money anyhow, without any limits,
according to the whims of the men in office, without any relation with the
existing production, there would definitely be runaway inflation. This is not at
all what is proposed here by the Social Crediters.
Accurate
bookkeeping
What the Social Crediters
advocate, when they speak of money created by the Government, is that money must
be brought back to its proper function, which is to be a figure, a ticket, that
represents products, which in fact is nothing but simple bookkeeping. And since
money is nothing but a bookkeeping system, the only necessary thing to do would
be to establish accurate bookkeeping:
The Government would appoint
a commission of accountants, an independent organism called the "National Credit
Office" (in Canada, the Bank of Canada could well carry out this job if ordered
to do so by the Government). This National Credit Office would be charged with
setting up accurate accounting, where money would be nothing but the reflection,
the exact financial expression, of economic realities: production would be
expressed in assets, and consumption in liabilities. Since one cannot consume
more than what has been produced, the liabilities could never exceed the assets,
and deficits and debts would be impossible.
In practice, here is how it
would work: the new money would be issued by the National Credit Office as new
products are made, and would be withdrawn from circulation as these products are
consumed (purchased). (Louis Even’s booklet, A Sound
and Effective Financial System, explains this mechanism in detail.) Thus
there would be no danger of having more money than products: there would be a
constant balance between money and products, money would always keep the same
value, and any inflation would be impossible. Money would not be issued
according to the whims of the Government nor of the accountants, since the
commission of accountants, appointed by the Government, would act only according
to the facts, according to what the Canadians produce and consume.
The best way to prevent any
price increase is to lower prices. And Social Credit does also propose a
mechanism to lower retail prices, called the "compensated discount", which would
allow the consumers to purchase all of the available production for sale with
the purchasing power they have at their disposal, by lowering retail prices (a
discount) by a certain percentage, so that the total retail prices of all the
goods for sale would equal the available total purchasing power of the consumer.
This discount would then be refunded to the retailers by the National Credit
Office. (This will be explained in Lesson 6.)
No more financial
problems
If the Government issued its
own money for the needs of society, it would be automatically able to pay for
all that can be produced in the country, and would no longer be obliged to
borrow from foreign or domestic financial institutions. The only taxes people
would pay would be for the services they consume. One would no longer have to
pay three or four times the actual price of public developments because of the
interest charges.
So, when the Government
would discuss a new project, it would not ask: "Do we have the money?", but: "Do
we have the materials and the workers to realize it?". If it is so, new money
would be automatically issued to finance this new production. Then the Canadians
could really live in accordance with their real means, the physical means, the
possibilities of production. In other words, all that is physically possible
would be made financially possible. There would be no more financial problems.
The only limit would be that of the producing capacity of the nation. The
Government would be able to finance all the developments and social programs
demanded by the population that are physically feasible.
Under the present debt-money
system, if the debt were to be paid off to the bankers, there would be no money
left in circulation, creating a depression infinitely worse than any of the
past. Let us quote again the exchange between Messrs. Patman and Eccles before
the House Banking and Currency Committee, on September 30, 1941:
Mr. Patman: "You have made
the statement that people should get out of debt instead of spending their
money. You recall the statement, I presume?"
Mr. Eccles: "That was in
connection with installment credit."
Mr. Patman: "Do you believe
that people should pay their debts generally when they can?"
Mr. Eccles: "I think it
depends a good deal upon the individual; but of course, if there were no debt in
our money system..."
Mr. Patman: "That is the
point I wanted to ask you about."
Mr. Eccles: "There wouldn’t
be any money."
Mr. Patman: "Suppose
everybody paid their debts, would we have any money to do business
on?"
Mr. Eccles: "That is
correct."
Mr. Patman: "In other words,
our system is based entirely on debt."
How can we ever hope to get
out of debt when all the money to pay off the debt is created by creating a
debt? Balancing the budget is an absurd straitjacket. What must be balanced is
the capacity to pay, in accordance with the capacity to produce, and not in
accordance with the capacity to tax. Since it is the capacity to produce that is
the reality, it is the capacity to pay that must be modeled on the capacity to
produce, to make financially possible what is physically feasible.
Repayment of the
debt
Paying off one’s debt is
simple justice if this debt is just. But if it is not the case, paying this debt
would be an act of weakness. As regards the public debt, justice is making no
debts at all, while developing the country. First, let us stop building new
debts. For the existing debt, the only bonds to be acknowledged would be those
of the savers; they who do not have the power to create money. The debt would
thus be reduced year after year, as bonds come to maturity.
The Government would honour
in full only the debts which, at their origins, represented a real expense on
the part of the creditor: the bonds purchased by individuals, and not the bonds
purchased with the money created by the banker, which are fictitious debts,
created by the stroke of a pen. As regards Third-World countries’ debts, they
are essentially owed to banks, which created all the money loaned to these
countries. These same countries would therefore have no interest charges to pay
back, and their debts would be, virtually, written off. Banks would lose
nothing, since it is they that had created this money, which did not exist
before.
John Paul II
|
Now we see how right are
those who call for a reform of the financial system and the cancellation of
debts, starting with Pope John Paul II, who wrote in his Apostolic Letter
Tertio Millennio Adveniente, for the celebration of the Jubilee of the
Year 2000:
"Thus, in the spirit of the
Book of Leviticus (25:8-12), Christians will have to raise their voice on behalf
of all the poor of the world, proposing the Jubilee as an appropriate time to
give thought, among other things, to reducing substantially, if not cancelling
outright, the international debt which seriously threatens the future of many
nations."
The social control of
money
|
St. Louis
IX
|
It is Saint Louis IX, King
of France, who said: "The first
duty of a king is to coin money when it is necessary for the sound economic life
of his subjects."
It is not at all necessary,
nor to be recommended, that banks be abolished or nationalized. The banker is an
expert in accounting and investing; he may well continue to receive and invest
savings with profit, taking his share of profits. But the creation of money is
an act of sovereignty which should not be left in the hands of a bank.
Sovereignty must be taken out of the hands of the banks and returned to the
nation.
Book money is a good modern
invention that should be retained. But instead of it proceeding from a private
pen, in the form of a debt, those figures, which serve as money, should come
from the pen of a national organism, in the form of money destined to serve the
people.
Therefore nothing is to be
turned upside down in the field of ownership or investment. There is no need to
abolish the current money and replace it with other kinds of money. All that is
needed is that a social monetary organism add enough of the same kind of money
to the money that already exists, according to the country’s possibilities and
the population’s needs.
We must stop suffering from
privations when there is everything needed in the country to bring comfort into
every home. The amount of money in circulation must be measured according to the
demand of the consumers for possible and useful goods.
It is therefore the
producers and consumers as a whole, the whole of society, which, in producing
goods to meet needs, should determine the amount of new money that an organism,
acting in the name of society, should put into circulation from time to time, in
accordance with the country’s developments.
Thus the people would
recover their right to live full lives, in accordance with the country’s
resources and the great possibilities of modern production.
Who owns the new
money?
Money should therefore be
put into circulation according to the rate of production and as the needs of
distribution dictate.
But to whom does this new
money belong when it comes into circulation in the country? — This money belongs
to the citizens themselves. It does not belong to the Government, which is not
the owner of the country, but only the protector of the common good; nor does it
belong to the accountants of the national monetary organism: like judges, they
carry out a social function and are paid, according to law, by society for their
services.
To which citizens? — To all.
This money is not a salary. It is new money injected into the public, so that
the people, as consumers, may obtain goods already made or easily realizable,
which are awaiting only sufficient purchasing power for them to be
produced.
One cannot imagine for one
moment that the new money, which comes gratuitously from a social organism, only
belongs to one or a few individuals in particular.
There is no other way, in
all fairness, of putting this new money into circulation than by distributing it
equally among all citizens without exception. Such a sharing also makes it
possible to derive the maximum benefit from the money, since it reaches into
every corner of the land.
Let us suppose that the
accountant who acts in the name of the nation finds it necessary to issue
another $1 million in order to meet the latest needs of the country. This
issuance could take the form of book money, the inscription of figures in
ledgers, as the banker does today.
Since there are 31 million
Canadians and 1 billion dollars to share, each citizen would get $32.25. So the
accountant would inscribe $32.25 in each citizen’s account. Such individual
accounts could easily be looked after by the local post offices, or by branches,
or by a bank owned by the nation.
This is the national
dividend. Each citizen would have an extra $32.25 to his own credit, in an
account bringing money into existence. This money would have been created and
put into circulation by a national monetary organism, an institution especially
established for this end by a law of Parliament.
To each the
dividend
Whenever it might become
necessary to increase the amount of money in a country, each man, woman and
child, regardless of age, would thus get his or her share of the new stage of
progress that makes the new money necessary.
This is not payment for a
job done, but a dividend to each one for his share in a common capital. If there
is private property, there is also community property that all possess in the
same way.
Here is a man who has
nothing but the rags he is covered with. Not a meal in front of him, not a penny
in his pocket. I can say to him:
"My dear fellow, you think
you are poor, but you are a capitalist who possesses a great deal of things in
the same way I and the Prime Minister do. The province’s waterfalls, the crown
forests, are yours as well as mine, and they can easily bring you in an annual
income.
"The social organization,
which makes it possible for our community to produce a hundred times more and
better than if we lived in isolation, is yours as well as mine, and must be
worth something to you as it is to me.
"Science, which makes
industry able to multiply production almost without human labour, is a heritage
passed on to each generation, a heritage that is continuously growing; and you,
who are a member of this generation just as I am, should have a share in this
legacy, just as I do.
"If you are poor and naked,
my friend, it is because your share has been stolen from you and put under lock
and key. When you have no food, it is not because the rich eat all the grain in
the land; it is because your share is still lying in the grain elevators. You
have been deprived of the means of getting that grain.
"The Social Credit dividend
will ensure that you get your share, or at least a major portion of it. A better
administration, freed from the financiers’ influence and able to cope with these
exploiters of men, will see to it that you get the rest.
"It is also this dividend
that will recognize you as a member of the human species, in virtue of which you
are entitled to a share of this world’s goods, at least the necessary share to
exercise your right to live."
Should money claim interest?
We believe that there is not
one thing in the world which lends itself to so much abuse as money. This is not
because money in itself is a bad thing. On the contrary, money is probably one
of man’s most brilliant inventions, making trade flexible, favouring the sale of
goods as required by needs, and making life in society easier.
But, to place money on an
altar is idolatry. To make of money a living thing, which gives birth to other
money, is unnatural.
Money does not breed money,
as the Greek philosopher Aristotle said. Yet, how many contracts are entered
into — contracts between individuals, contracts between governments and
creditors, which stipulate that money must breed money, or else properties or
freedoms are forfeited?
Little by little, everybody
has sided behind the theory, and especially behind the practice, that money must
produce interest. And in spite of all the Christian teaching to the contrary,
the practice has made so much headway that, so as not to lose in the furious
competition around the fertility of money, everybody must behave today as if it
was natural for money to breed money. The Church has not abrogated her old laws,
but it has become impossible for her to insist on their application.
The methods used to finance
World War II, in which we were Churchill, Roosevelt, and Stalin’s acolytes to
defend Christianity, solemnly consecrated the rule that money, even money thrown
into the sea or into the burning flames of cities, must bear interest. We refer
here to the Victory Bonds, which financed destruction, which did not produce
anything, and which had to bear interest just the same.
Interest and
dividends
So that our readers do not
pass out thinking about their savings put into industry or loan institutions,
let us hastily make a few distinctions.
If money cannot increase by
itself, there are things that money buys which logically produce developments.
Thus
I set aside $5,000 to
purchase a farm, or animals, seeds, trees, machinery. With intelligent work, I
will make these things produce others.
The $5,000 was an
investment. By itself it has not produced anything; but thanks to this $5,000, I
have been able to get things that have produced.
Let us suppose that I did
not have this $5,000. But my neighbour had it, and he did not need it for a
couple of weeks. He loaned it to me. I think it would be proper for me to show
my gratitude by letting him have a small portion of the products which I get,
thanks to the productive capital which I have thus been able to
obtain.
It is my work which has made
his capital profitable. But this capital itself represents accumulated work. We
are then two, whose activities — gone by for him, present for me — cause some
production to appear. The fact that he waited to draw on the country’s
production with the money he received as a reward for his work allowed me to get
the means of production that I would not have had without it.
We are therefore able to
divide the fruits of this collaboration between us. There remains to determine,
by agreement and equity, the part of production that is owed to the
capital.
What my lender will get in
this case is, strictly speaking, a dividend. (We divided the fruits of
production.)
The dividend is perfectly
justifiable, when production is fruitful.
* * *
This is not exactly the idea
that is generally attached to the word "interest". Interest is a claim made by
money, in function of time only, and independently of the results of the
loan.
Here is $1,000. I invest it
in federal, provincial, or municipal bonds. If I purchase bonds that bear 4%
interest, I ought to get $40 in interest every year, just as truly as the earth
will make one revolution around the sun during this period of time. Even if the
capital is used up without any profit, I must get my $40. That is
interest.
We cannot see anything that
justifies this claim, save that it is customary. It does not rest upon any
principle.
There is therefore
justification for a dividend, because it is subordinated to production growth.
There is no justification for interest in itself, because it is dissociated from
realities; it is based on the erroneous idea of a natural and periodical
generation of money.
Indirect
investments
In practice, he who brings
his money to the bank indirectly puts it into a productive industry. The bankers
are professional lenders, and the depositor passes his money to them, because
they are capable of making it thrive better than he can, without having to look
after it himself.
The small interest that the
banker enters to the depositor’s credit from time to time, even at fixed rates,
is in fact a dividend, a share from the income that the banker, with the help of
the borrowers, has obtained from productive activities.
Anonymous
investments
In passing, let us say a
word on the morality of investments. Many people are not preoccupied in the
least with the usefulness or the noxiousness of activities that their money will
finance. As long as it yields profits, they say, it is good. And the more profit
it yields, the better the investment is. A pagan would not reason
differently.
If a house-owner does not
have the right to rent his house to serve as a brothel, even though it would be
very profitable, the owner of savings does not have any more right to put them
into enterprises which ruin souls, even if the enterprises fill
pockets.
Moreover, it would be much
preferable for the backer and the entrepreneur to be less dissociated. The
smaller industry of old was much more sound: The financier and the entrepreneur
were the same person. The corner storekeeper is still in the same situation. The
chain stores are not. The co-operative, the association of people, keeps the
relation between the use of money and its owner, and has the advantage of making
possible enterprises which exceed the resources of one sole
individual.
The growth of
money
Let us go back to the
beginning question: Should money claim interest? We are therefore inclined to
answer: Money can claim dividends when there are fruits. Otherwise,
no.
If contracts are drafted
differently, if the farmer must pay back interest, even though he did not
receive any crop that year; if the farmers of Western Canada must honour
liabilities at 7%, when the Financiers who lead the world cause prices to fall
to one-third of what they were, this does not change anything about the
principle. The only thing this proves is that reality has been exchanged for
trickery.
But if money can claim
dividends, when there is a production increase, this production increase must
automatically create an increase in money. Otherwise, the dividend, while being
perfectly justifiable, becomes impossible to provide without dealing a blow to
the public from which it was extracted.
I was saying a few lines
above: If, thanks to the $5,000 which allowed me to buy ploughing implements, I
have increased my production, the lender is entitled to a share of these good
results. This is very easy to do if I let him have a share of these increased
products. But if it is money that I must give to him, it is quite another story.
If there is no increase of money in the public, my increased production creates
a problem: more offered goods, but no increase of money in step with them. I may
be successful at displacing another seller, but he will be the
victim.
You can tell me that the
$5,000 must have contributed to increasing money in circulation. Yes, but I must
pump back the $5,000, plus what I call the dividend, what others call
interest.
Then the problem is not
settled. And in our economic system, it cannot be. For money to increase, it is
necessary that the bank — the only place where the increase is created — lends
some somewhere. But in lending it, the bank exacts a repayment that is also
increased. The problem snowballs.
The Social Credit system
would settle that problem, as well as settle many other problems.
The dividend is a
legitimate, normal, logical thing. But the present system does not allow anyone
to pay it without making it hurt somewhere.
Our Lord drives the money
changers out of the Temple
As a matter of fact, the only passage in the
Gospel where it is mentioned that Jesus used force is when He drove the money
changers out of the Temple with a scourge of cords, and overthrew their tables
(as reported in Matthew 21:12-13 and Mark 11:15-19), precisely because they were
lending money at interest.
There was, at that time, a
law that the tithes or taxes of the Temple could be paid only in one certain
coin called the "half shekel of the sanctuary", of which the money changers had
managed to obtain the monopoly. There were several different coins at that time,
but the people had to obtain this particular coin with which to pay their Temple
Tax. Moreover, the doves and the animals that the people bought for sacrifice
also could only be bought with this same special coin that the money changers
exchanged to the pilgrims, but at a cost of twice or more times its actual
worth, when it was used to buy commodities. So Jesus overthrew their tables, and
said:
"My house shall be called a
house of prayer; but you have made it a den of thieves."
The teaching of the
Church
The Bible contains several
texts that clearly condemn the lending of money at interest. Moreover, more than
300 years before Jesus Christ, the great Greek philosopher Aristotle also
condemned lending at interest, pointing out that "money, being naturally barren,
to make it breed money is preposterous." Furthermore, the Fathers of the Church,
since the remotest times, always unequivocally denounced usury. Saint Thomas
Aquinas, in his Summa Theologica (2, 2, Q. 78), thus summarized the teaching of
the Church on lending money at interest:
St. Thomas Aquinas
|
"It is written in the Book
of Exodus (22, 24): `If you lend money to any of my people who are poor, that
dwells with you, you shall not be hard upon them as an extortioner, nor oppress
them with usury.’ He who takes usury for a loan of money acts unjustly, for he
sells what does not exist, and such an action evidently constitutes an
inequality and, consequently, an injustice... It follows then that it is wrong
in itself to take a price (usury) for the use of money lent, and as in the case
of other offenses against justice, one is bound to make restitution of his
unjustly acquired money."
In reply to the text of the
Gospel on the parable of the talents (Matthew 25:14-30 and Luke 19:12-27) which,
at first sight, seems to justify interest ("Wicked and slothful servant... why
did you not put my money into the bank, so that I might have recovered it with
interest when I came?"), Saint Thomas Aquinas wrote:
"The interest mentioned in
the Gospel must be taken in a figurative sense; it means the additional
spiritual goods asked of us by God, who wants us to always make better use of
the goods He entrusted us with, but this is for our benefit and not
His."
So this text of the Gospel
cannot justify interest since, as Saint Thomas says, "an argument cannot be
based on figurative expressions."
Another passage of the Bible
that presents difficulties is Deuteronomy 23:20-21: "You shall not demand
interest from your brother on a loan of money or food or of anything else. You
may demand interest from a foreigner, but not from your brother." Saint Thomas
explains:
"The Jews were forbidden to
take interest from `their brothers’, that is to say, from other Jews; this means
that demanding interest on a loan from anyone is wrong, strictly speaking, for
one must consider every man as `one’s neighbour and brother’, especially
according to the evangelical law that must rule mankind. So the Psalmist,
talking about the just man, says unreservedly: `he who lends not his money at
usury’ (14:4) and Ezekiel (18:17): `a son who accepts no interest or
usury’."
If the Jews were allowed to
demand interest from a foreigner, Saint Thomas wrote, it was tolerated in order
to avoid a greater evil, for fear that they might charge interest to other Jews,
the worshippers of the true God. Saint Ambrose, commenting on the same text,
gives to the word "foreigners" the meaning of "enemies", and concludes: "One may
seek interest from the one he legitimately wants to harm, from the one whom it
is lawful to wage war with."
Saint Ambrose also said:
"What is usury, if not killing a man?"
Saint John Chrysostom:
"Nothing is more shameful or cruel than usury."
Saint Leo: "The avarice that
claims to do its neighbour a good turn while it deceives him is unjust and
insolent... He who, among the other rules of a pious conduct, will not have lent
his money at usury, will enjoy eternal rest... whereas he who gets richer to the
detriment of others deserves, in return, eternal damnation."
In 1311, at the Council of
Vienna, Pope Clement V declared null and void all secular legislation in favour
of usury, and "all who fall into the error of obstinately, maintaining that the
exaction of usury is not sinful, shall be punished as
heretics."
Vix
pervenit
|
Benedict
XIV
|
On November 1, 1745, Pope
Benedict XIV issued the encyclical letter Vix Pervenit, addressed
to the Bishops of Italy, about contracts, and in which usury, or money-lending
at interest, is clearly condemned. On July 29, 1836, Pope Gregory XVI extended
this encyclical to the whole Church. It says:
"The kind of sin called
usury, which lies in the loan, consists in the fact that someone, using as an
excuse the loan itself — which by nature requires one to give back only as much
as one has received — demands to receive more than is due to him, and
consequently maintains that, besides the capital, a profit is due to him,
because of the loan itself. It is for this reason that any profit of this kind
that exceeds the capital is illicit and usurious.
"And in order not to bring
upon oneself this infamous note, it would be useless to say that this profit is
not excessive but moderate; that it is not large, but small... For the object of
the law of lending is necessarily the equality between what is lent and what is
given back... Consequently, if someone receives more than he lent, he is bound
in commutative justice to restitution..."
In 1891, Pope Leo XIII wrote
in his Encyclical Letter Rerum Novarum: "The mischief has been increased by rapacious usury, which,
although more than once condemned by the Church, is nevertheless, under a
different guise, but with like injustice, still practiced by covetous and
grasping men. "
On this matter, it is
interesting to consider the experience of the Islamic banks: the Koran — the
holy book of the Moslems — forbids usury, as the Bible of the Christians does.
But the Moslems took these words seriously and have set up, since 1979, a
banking system that conforms with the rules of the Koran: Islamic banks charge
no interest on neither current nor deposit accounts. They invest in business,
and pay a share of any profits to their depositors. This is not the Social
Credit system implemented in its entirety yet but, at least, it is a more than
worthy attempt at putting the banking system in keeping with moral
laws.
Very interesting but extremely difficult to read blue text on a red background.
ReplyDeleteSorry you found it difficult to read the text because of the blue text but that is how the template of this blog is set up for now. But at least you found it interesting. Personally, I have had no trouble reading the blue text.
ReplyDeleteAnyway, thank you for your response.