Showing posts with label electronic money. Show all posts
Showing posts with label electronic money. Show all posts

Wednesday, 27 May 2015

The Potential of Electronic Money for Social Good


05 October 2012
The efforts of the global development community to harness the power of electronic money for the social good got a big shot in the arm last week.  On the sidelines of the 2012 UN General Assembly a coalition of leading countries, global NGO’s, development agencies and the private sector came together and formed the “Better-Than-Cash” Alliance.   This coalition can make a real difference.  The leading country members (Colombia, Kenya, Peru, and the Philippines) are already shifting their own payment flows onto electronic platforms. Global NGOs are doing so as well. And the donor members (including the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, Ford Foundation, Omidyar, USAID) and corporations (Citi and Visa) are willing to put up additional seed funding to help others follow the lead.
The development field has had its fair share of promising silver bullets and subsequent disappointments.   So it’s probably important to parse the considerable upside electronic money can bring about, but also to understand where the issues go beyond better-than-cash transactions.  Essentially, for the development community, there are two separate promises and the potentially beneficial interaction between the two that have created excitement.
The first promise is on financial inclusion.  More than 75% percent of the world’s poor are excluded from formal financial services according to 2011 World Bank/Gallup data.  They typically work and live in the informal economy and need financial access as much as anyone else to build assets, create livelihoods, manage risks and smooth consumption.  Living on average below $2 dollars a day does not mean you have $2 dollars every day.  Without access to formal financial services, poor families have to rely on age-old informal mechanisms:  Families & friends, rotating savings schemes, the pawn-broker, the moneylender, money under the mattress.  These informal mechanisms can be very unreliable and are often very expensive.
Electronic money, in particular mobile-phone-based, has the proven potential to reach far more people at lower costs than traditional brick-and-mortar, for example for domestic remittances or low denomination, short-term money safekeeping.  A ubiquitous, low-cost electronic retail payment platform will also make new business models viable that rely on collecting huge numbers of tiny amounts, for example user fees for community-based infrastructure such as off-grid solar power.  In Kenya, where M-Pesa by now reaches 80%+ of the population, we are seeing a wave of this second-generation business model innovation happen.   
But transaction costs are only one part of financial intermediation. Take long-horizon, term-savings that functions as a micro-pension for example.  There is a real need for such a product as traditional multi-generational families are breaking up over urban migration of the next generation and uptake has been very high where offered.  Some financial intermediary has to actually make the asset/liability transformation and earn the promised 5-6 percent annual real rate of return over 10, 15 years plus some to cover administrative costs and margin.  Or take insurance:  Some financial intermediary has to aggregate diverse exposures at actuarially-relevant scale and properly manage and reinsure that pooled risk so that claims can be paid out and the corpus remains solvent in the event of a large-scale crop failures or wide-spread property-damage.  Lower transaction costs help, but are not a sufficient condition for the viability of these forms of financial intermediation required for real welfare gains.
The second promise of electronic money is on the effectiveness and efficiency of government, development, and NGO payments, in particular for social protection purposes.  Governments in developing countries spend tens of billions each year on social transfer payments.  Some of these do very good.  In some cases, the transaction costs of handing out cash eat up a significant share, and leakage through local-level corruption can be immense.  Electronic payments combined with unique IDs have the potential to dramatically increase effectiveness in the targeting and efficiency in the distribution of such transfers.  The Indian  Government, for example, has announced its intention to shift over a myriad of existing programs, the cash leakage for some of which have been estimated to be as high as 40 percent.
In Brazil, the Bolsa Familia program reduced its transaction costs from 14.7 percent of total to 2.6 percent when it bundled several benefits onto one electronic payment card.  But social transfers are still social transfers.  Somebody has to pay for them. And to ensure that a social transfer enables poor families to graduate into sustainable livelihoods likely requires other costly interventions, such as skills training, financial capability building, and an asset transfer such as livestock that creates future income streams.
The third promise of electronic money is a beneficial interaction between financial inclusion and social transfer payment flows.  An inclusive financial system that reaches all citizens allows for more effective and efficient targeting of other social policies, such as conditional payments in health or education, for example when parents are rewarded for making sure their children get all recommended vaccinations or for sending their girls go to school.  Conversely, a shift of the often large government payment flows can truly catalyze the development of the inclusive financial system by bringing previously excluded segments into the financial system and lowering everybody else’s transaction costs.
For this virtuous cycle to kick in a number of elements must line up.  Social protection ministries must be convinced that the electronic payment route meets their primary objectives.  Governments must be willing to pay providers for the usage of a general purpose, retail payment infrastructure.  In early examples, governments built closed-loop, single-purpose electronic mechanisms that can be more expensive than cash.  Beneficiaries must trust the system.
In many early schemes, poor families converted their monthly electronic deposit immediately into cash because they feared that accumulating a savings balance might exclude them from being a transfer beneficiary in the future.  Based on these findings, countries and the global development community are learning and improving design and execution of their programs.  The “Better-than-Cash” Alliance is picking up on this learning and has thrown its considerable weight behind an exciting global effort.              
Topics: 

Source Ref



The Data Journey  (video)






Monday, 6 January 2014

Electronic Money


Blogger Ref Link http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics



Electronic money is a new expression the meaning of which is not stable. It can refer to different realities depending on the context (legal or not, historical or actual, monetary theory...).
However, the underlying principle of electronic money involves the use of computer networks, the Internet and digital stored value systems. Examples of electronic money are bank deposits, electronic funds transfer (EFT), direct deposit, payment processors, and digital currencies such as Bitcoin.


Electronic money definitions[edit]

Law[edit]

Since 2001, the European Union has implemented a directive "on the taking up, pursuit and prudential supervision of the business of electronic money institutions" last amended in 2009.[1]
However, doubts on the real nature of the EU Electronic money have arrised since calls have been made in favour of a merger of Payment institutions from Payment Services Directive and Electonic money institutions from homonym directive. Indeed, such a merger could mean that electronic money is in reality of the same nature as bank money or scriptural money.

Monetary theory and history of monetary ideas[edit]

Monetary classfications usually distinguish different types of money : commodity money, Fiat money, ... Electronic Money would be a different form of money altogether.

Electronic money systems around the world[edit]

While electronic money has been an interesting problem for cryptography, to date, the use of e-money has been relatively low-scale. One rare success has been Hong Kong's Octopus card system, which started as a transit payment system and has grown into a widely used electronic money system. London Transport's Oyster card system remains essentially a contactless pre-paid travelcard. Two other cities have implemented functioning electronic money systems. Very similar to Hong Kong's Octopus card, Singapore has an electronic money program for its public transportation system (commuter trains, bus, etc.), based on the same type of (FeliCa) system invented by Sony and first deployed in Tokyo and Osaka, Japan. The Netherlands has also implemented a nationwide electronic money system known as Chipknip for general purpose, as well as OV-Chipkaart for transit fare collection. In Belgium, a payment service company, Proton, owned by 60 Belgian banks issuing stored value cards, was developed in 1995.[2]
A number of electronic money systems use contactless payment transfer in order to facilitate easy payment and give the payee more confidence in not letting go of their electronic wallet during the transaction. The idea of a future with only electronic money has been met with controversy.[3]

Electronic money systems[edit]

Centralised systems[edit]

Many systems—such as PayPal, WebMoney, Payoneer, cashU, and Hub Culture's Ven—will sell their electronic currency directly to the end user, but other systems only sell through third party digital currency exchangers.
In Kenya, the M-Pesa system is being used to transfer money through mobile phones.
Some community currencies, like some local exchange trading systems (LETS) and the Community Exchange System, work with electronic transactions.

Decentralised systems[edit]

Decentralised electronic money systems include:the currency

Mobile sub-systems[edit]

A number of electronic money systems use contactless payment transfer in order to facilitate easy payment and give the payee more confidence in not letting go of their electronic wallet during the transaction.

Hard vs. soft electronic currencies[edit]

A hard electronic currency is one that does not have services to dispute or reverse charges. In other words, it only supports non-reversible transactions. Reversing transactions, even in case of a legitimate error, unauthorized use, or failure of a vendor to supply goods is difficult, if not impossible. The advantage of this arrangement is that the operating costs of the electronic currency system are greatly reduced by not having to resolve payment disputes. Additionally, it allows the electronic currency transactions to clear instantly, making the funds available immediately to the recipient. This means that using hard electronic currency is more akin to a cash transaction. Examples are Western Union, KlickEx and Bitcoin.
A soft electronic currency is one that allows for reversal of payments, for example in case of fraud or disputes. Reversible payment methods generally have a "clearing time" of 72 hours or more. Examples are PayPal and credit card.
A hard currency can be softened by using a trusted third party or an escrow service.

See also[edit]

References[edit]


Wednesday, 20 February 2013

Improved Macroeconomic Control with Electronic Money and Modern Monetary Theory



The following is a link of a paper which deals with Modern Monetary Theory, and electronic money by  Trond Andresen. This is what he had to say




"Approximately a month back I posted a link to a working paper discussing the very (in my opinion) exciting potential of combining MMT with electronic money (= no physical currency). The paper has now been revised and fleshed out, see link




Any reactions appreciated!(Also, if there is bad English, or typos)."


Also, Trond Andresen made the point that he realized the importance of electronic money before June 2010 at least.. as the following article indicates. Incidently, his paper falls short of my evolving project of Transfinancial Economics, but it is certainly a step in the right direction. The importance of money = electronic data is absolutely vital, and could hold the key to the survival, and success of the human race......

http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics




 
Local Exhange Trading Systems

What If the Greeks Did This?

by TROND ANDRESEN  Counterpunch  Weekend Edition June 25-27, 2010
Worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for the reputation to fail conventionally than to succeed unconventionally”
– John Maynard Keynes
This is an attempt to think outside the box, because any sorts of thinking inside the box on Greece and countries in similar situations hasn’t led to anything and will not either. But if the reader knows about some unconventional proposal that I may have overlooked, point me to it!
Here follows my proposal – comments are welcome:
An alliance of large grass roots organisation (typically: unions) sets up a cooperative bank-like operation ("BLO"). Probably it should formally be an association requiring membership to participate (more on this below). This BLO issues "value points" (an arbitrarily chosen term, from now on abbreviated "VP’s" — it could be called "units", "work units", "credits", "coupons", whatever — but should for legal reasons not be called "money" or "Drachmas"). Technically, the BLO is just a national office with computer capacity and a few employees. There are no branches. A member gets a VP "account" with the BLO. To use the account the member needs a mobile phone subscription. When opening an account, (s)he is automatically offered credit up to a standard amount of VP’s from the BLO. Such a "start loan" has the purpose of enabling the person to start transacting with others. It is primarily meant as a medium of exchange, and not as a store of value. It is interest-free, but there is a very small membership fee per account, which is only to cover the expenses of the BLO office and computer/network costs. This fee must be paid in Euros/regular money. The VP loan has limited duration, a few months. When the loan expires, the borrower has the right to an automatically renewed loan, but the maximum amount allowed may have been adjusted somewhat up or down in relation to the last loan received. More on this below.
Technological progress makes this possible
What is to be proposed here is a national and extremely efficient version of a LETS (Local Exchange Trading System), or a local currency system. These are basically barter schemes but strongly improved by using a local medium of exchange. Members gain points by supplying goods or services to other members. Such points gained are in the next round used to buy goods or services from other participants. The big advantage is that this enables economic activities locally which would else not have taken place due to lack of a regular medium of exchange (i.e. money). A LETS system has traditionally been managed by some trusted person(s) keeping tally of everyones’ points account on a computer. This is done when reports of exchanges are received. Such a system is only manageable when it is confined to some local community. Another factor limiting the geographical and population scope of such schemes is that participants need to know which other agents (persons, firms) are also in the scheme, and what sort of services or goods they offer.
A local currency system does a similar job as a LETS scheme. In that case one may have circulating paper currency resembling regular money, something that eliminates the need for account updates with each transaction, but which may be legally difficult to uphold due to the state’s monopoly on money issuance.
A LETS-like scheme must do the following:
* account for transactions (or run a local monetary system)
* give participants an easy and fast way to find other agents in the system and what they offer (or demand).
Today, with most people having mobile phones, and also access to the Internet (whether at home, work or elsewhere), both challenges may be elegantly and cheaply met, and "the local community" may be expanded to encompass a country. Reporting of transactions is done via mobile phone/SMS and automatically received and accounted for on a server. And a web site data base (possibly on the same server), updated by participants and having a Google-like search system, will enable participants to advertise themselves or to easily find sellers and and buyers anywhere of the relevant goods or services.
Gradual increase in transactions
Mobile phone transactions with other BLO members may be implemented through one of the technically proven schemes already in operation in some developing countries. There are no physical/paper VP’s in circulation. People and firms offering goods and services will gradually – as the scheme gets more popular – decide to accept a certain share of VP’s as payment, while the rest must still be in Euros. Such a share is decided freely and individually by the seller, and may also be adjusted at any time with circumstances. The same holds for wages: employers and employees may as the scheme gets widely accepted, agree on a certain share of wages being paid in VP’s, a share that may be re-negotiated as things develop.
Pure fiat money
The VP’s are pure fiat money. They do not have any property giving it an intrinsic value like money issued by a central bank, which has indisputable value by being the sole currency that may be used to pay taxes (as per the "modern money" or "Chartalist" view). People or firms will therefore accept VP’s in payment only if they believe that a sufficient amount of other people/firms will accept them. This outcome is probable however, since today’s only alternative for the Greeks (and other nations in a similar situation) of too low and further shrinking income in Euros over many years, is much worse.
Building confidence
Such a scheme has dynamics which may be unstable both ways: confidence building more confidence, or decreasing confidence leading to hyperinflation and collapse. One should ensure a basic and initial level of confidence by the BLO being launched and run by (a) large, national and well established organisation(s). Second, and most important, by controlling the amount of VP’s in circulation, based on observing the average acceptance of VP’s as a share of payment together with Euros, it should be possible to uphold the needed amount of confidence in the system. The amount in circulation may be limited by renewing loans with a lower amount when earlier loans expire. Then the borrower will have to accept a reduction of the amount in his/hers account. To avoid runaway inflation in VP’s, one should probably start the process by issuing a restricted amount (see below), and then letting the aggregate amount grow (or in between shrink) based on the observed impact. Note that the existence of VP’s only as electronic entities on a computer (no physical "currency"), combined with the fact that the initial issued loan has not in any way been "earned" by the account holder, allows the scheme to freely regulate the amount of VP’s in circulation upwards or even downwards, by adjusting all accounts with the same amount. This is a new and potent macroeconomic control instrument that is not available in a regular monetary system.
Why is membership necessary?
As already mentioned, the BLO should be organised as an association requiring membership. Then the VP’s are not a state-controlled medium of exchange like Euros, but a device for members to exchange goods and labour between them. Hopefully this will make it difficult for the state to ban such a system, something it will possibly or even probably want to do.
There is a further good argument for membership requirement: One should avoid giving the well-to-do a free lunch in the form of an automatic BLO loan, on top of the ample buying power they possess in Euros. They should as a rule only be allowed to open an account, but not have access to an automatically given and renewed VP loan. The BLO should be targeted towards the less well-off in society. This may be achieved by having two grades of membership. Level 1 is open to all (including firms): you get an account but no initial loan. Level 2 (call it "core" membership) additionally qualifies for the loan. Core membership should only be given to people already belonging to one or more of the organisations behind the BLO (unions and similar popular organisations, for instance farmers’), and to the unemployed. And it should be automatically given, to give the scheme a flying start.
One could modify the rules somewhat by allowing level 2 membership for persons that do not initially qualify, but who are recommended by a core member. But it is probably wise to start the process carefully by only giving automatic loans to core members, and later relax the rules in a controlled manner, based on how things develop. Account holders that default on their loans above some defined level of transgression may be excluded as members of the system, and their accounts discontinued.
Credit above the automatic amount?
In an initial period, the system should be simple and only have the purpose of enabling transactions between agents that lack a medium of exchange. If the scheme exhibits strong growth and widening acceptance, the possibility of extending larger VP loans to applicants may be considered. But this would demand a dramatic increase in the staff and organisation complexity of the BLO because loan applicants have to be vetted and collateral has to be posted.
Political resistance
On may expect that such a scheme will be opposed by the state and derided by the economic establishment, including most media pundits. But criticism in itself is not a fundamental obstacle. A bigger danger is whether the scheme may be banned based on the country’s laws, like the Austrian state did in 1933 against the succesful local currency in the town of Wörgl. Hopefully, organising the scheme as an association with transactions only being available to members and no money-like paper VP’s in circulation, will prevent such an outcome.
Another and perhaps more surprising source of resistance may be the leadership in some of the mass organisations whose members would benefit from such a scheme. Many such leaders are anchored in a marxist/communist/left socialist tradition. The proposal may easily be seen by some of these as a "petty bourgeouis" invention of the "green" "alternative" type, only giving the masses "illusions" and "leading them astray in the struggle against capitalism and for socialism".
Better than the only and bleak alternative
By the proposed scheme it should be possible to activate a large underused potential that Greece (and other Eurozone countries) has, unemployed or underemployed people. It will also primarily stimulate domestic production, since VP’s may not be used to pay for imports. Enabling unemployed or underemployed people to work for each other and (increasingly) to exchange goods and services with the rest of society, will – with immediate effects – ameliorate the dramatic and persistent decrease in living standards for most people, which is the bleak and only future (lasting many years) that the powers that be and most pundits are able to come up with.
(Note however: possibly the best solution would have been to revert to a national currency combined with partial foreign currency debt forgiveness, as argued by some dissident voices. But this seems to be politically totally out of the question for those in power. Therefore the above "VP" proposal.)
Trond Andressen is a lecturer in the Department of Engineering Cybernetics at the Norwegian University of Science and Technology in Trondheim. He can be reached at: trond.andresen@itk.ntnu.no.
 

Saturday, 26 January 2013

"Improved Macroeconomic Control with Electronic Money and Modern Monetary Theory".


A working paper:



Abstract: This paper combines the concept of electronic money (no physical currency) with Modern Monetary Theory. It argues how electronic monetary systems offer a big step forward for macroeconomic control, among other things by giving a government new and potent steering tools. More specifically the paper discusses how one in an electronic money environment can easily curb an overheated economy – admittedly far from today's global situation – but a necessary topic all the same to convince people that running large and persistent government budget deficits in depressed economies, is not "irresponsible" and does not need to imply strong inflation in later economic boom situations.


Any reactions appreciated!
Trond Andresen.
 
http://www.itk.ntnu.no/ansatte/Andresen_Trond/econ/mmt-electronic.pdf
www.itk.ntnu.no


Interesting! Trond, I think you must have got some of your inspriation from my evolving project of Transfinancial Economics. Electronic money is the key to the future understanding of economics. Ofcourse, TFE though goes alot further than your presentation because it most notably offers the possibility of gaining a highly accurate undertstanding of the economy itself in real-time. This, ofcourse, is revolutionary par excellence,and would spell the end of economics as we know it. Moreover, we would have a situation in which new money could be created WITH REAL CONFIDENCE where necessary electronically in such a way as to avoid serious inflationary consequences...rather than continually using "indirect" methods of taxation, and interest rates rises.


Above message from Robert Searle, the onsite bloger of The Economic Realms.

http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics (Relevant references will be included in my present "work in progress" "paper" shortly.

Tuesday, 8 January 2013

The Potential of Electronic Money for Social Good

October 5, 2012

The efforts of the global development community to harness the power of electronic money for the social good got a big shot in the arm last week.  On the sidelines of the 2012 UN General Assembly a coalition of leading countries, global NGO’s, development agencies and the private sector came together and formed the “Better-Than-Cash” Alliance.   This coalition can make a real difference.  The leading country members (Colombia, Kenya, Peru, and the Philippines) are already shifting their own payment flows onto electronic platforms. Global NGOs are doing so as well. And the donor members (including the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, Ford Foundation, Omidyar, USAID) and corporations (Citi and Visa) are willing to put up additional seed funding to help others follow the lead.
The development field has had its fair share of promising silver bullets and subsequent disappointments.   So it’s probably important to parse the considerable upside electronic money can bring about, but also to understand where the issues go beyond better-than-cash transactions.  Essentially, for the development community, there are two separate promises and the potentially beneficial interaction between the two that have created excitement.
The first promise is on financial inclusion.  More than 75% percent of the world’s poor are excluded from formal financial services according to 2011 World Bank/Gallup data.  They typically work and live in the informal economy and need financial access as much as anyone else to build assets, create livelihoods, manage risks and smooth consumption.  Living on average below $2 dollars a day does not mean you have $2 dollars every day.  Without access to formal financial services, poor families have to rely on age-old informal mechanisms:  Families & friends, rotating savings schemes, the pawn-broker, the moneylender, money under the mattress.  These informal mechanisms can be very unreliable and are often very expensive.
Electronic money, in particular mobile-phone-based, has the proven potential to reach far more people at lower costs than traditional brick-and-mortar, for example for domestic remittances or low denomination, short-term money safekeeping.  A ubiquitous, low-cost electronic retail payment platform will also make new business models viable that rely on collecting huge numbers of tiny amounts, for example user fees for community-based infrastructure such as off-grid solar power.  In Kenya, where M-Pesa by now reaches 80%+ of the population, we are seeing a wave of this second-generation business model innovation happen.   
But transaction costs are only one part of financial intermediation. Take long-horizon, term-savings that functions as a micro-pension for example.  There is a real need for such a product as traditional multi-generational families are breaking up over urban migration of the next generation and uptake has been very high where offered.  Some financial intermediary has to actually make the asset/liability transformation and earn the promised 5-6 percent annual real rate of return over 10, 15 years plus some to cover administrative costs and margin.  Or take insurance:  Some financial intermediary has to aggregate diverse exposures at actuarially-relevant scale and properly manage and reinsure that pooled risk so that claims can be paid out and the corpus remains solvent in the event of a large-scale crop failures or wide-spread property-damage.  Lower transaction costs help, but are not a sufficient condition for the viability of these forms of financial intermediation required for real welfare gains.
The second promise of electronic money is on the effectiveness and efficiency of government, development, and NGO payments, in particular for social protection purposes.  Governments in developing countries spend tens of billions each year on social transfer payments.  Some of these do very good.  In some cases, the transaction costs of handing out cash eat up a significant share, and leakage through local-level corruption can be immense.  Electronic payments combined with unique IDs have the potential to dramatically increase effectiveness in the targeting and efficiency in the distribution of such transfers.  The Indian  Government, for example, has announced its intention to shift over a myriad of existing programs, the cash leakage for some of which have been estimated to be as high as 40 percent.
In Brazil, the Bolsa Familia program reduced its transaction costs from 14.7 percent of total to 2.6 percent when it bundled several benefits onto one electronic payment card.  But social transfers are still social transfers.  Somebody has to pay for them. And to ensure that a social transfer enables poor families to graduate into sustainable livelihoods likely requires other costly interventions, such as skills training, financial capability building, and an asset transfer such as livestock that creates future income streams.
The third promise of electronic money is a beneficial interaction between financial inclusion and social transfer payment flows.  An inclusive financial system that reaches all citizens allows for more effective and efficient targeting of other social policies, such as conditional payments in health or education, for example when parents are rewarded for making sure their children get all recommended vaccinations or for sending their girls go to school.  Conversely, a shift of the often large government payment flows can truly catalyze the development of the inclusive financial system by bringing previously excluded segments into the financial system and lowering everybody else’s transaction costs.
For this virtuous cycle to kick in a number of elements must line up.  Social protection ministries must be convinced that the electronic payment route meets their primary objectives.  Governments must be willing to pay providers for the usage of a general purpose, retail payment infrastructure.  In early examples, governments built closed-loop, single-purpose electronic mechanisms that can be more expensive than cash.  Beneficiaries must trust the system.
In many early schemes, poor families converted their monthly electronic deposit immediately into cash because they feared that accumulating a savings balance might exclude them from being a transfer beneficiary in the future.  Based on these findings, countries and the global development community are learning and improving design and execution of their programs.  The “Better-than-Cash” Alliance is picking up on this learning and has thrown its considerable weight behind an exciting global effort.

The Article above comes the blog of the following organization.