Showing posts with label monetary policy. Show all posts
Showing posts with label monetary policy. Show all posts

Friday, 13 September 2013

Forward Guidance

Blogger Ref link http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics




Posted on by



      
There has been a very important development of the UK economic policy regime this summer that deserves scrutiny by anyone interested in the future path of the UK economy.
The new Governor of the Bank of England, Mark Carney, has persuaded the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) to adopt a new approach to monetary policy.  Based on North American models, it introduces a more direct link between monetary policy and the real economy.  It aims to achieve three things: first, to calm fears that interest rates are likely to rise soon; second to support the short-term recovery; and, third, to provide a longer term framework that can influence market and inflation expectations.
In its latest Inflation Report, the Bank sees the prospects for UK growth as higher than before.  But, for inflation, its outlook is unchanged.  Importantly, the path of its growth forecasts (2-3% per annum over 2014-16) is not sufficient to remove the slack in the economy.  Because of this persistent degree of spare capacity (and negative/low real wage increases), underlying inflation is likely to remain subdued.  The MPC does acknowledge, however, that administrative and import price rises are still holding the rate of increase in the consumer price index (CPI) above target (2.8% in the year to July compared with a target of 2%).  Indeed, the target is not expected to be hit until well into 2015.
By May 2013, forward market interest rates had started to rise in response to better economic prospects.  The Bank, particularly Mr Carney, feared that expectations of interest rate increases were premature and that they might cut off a real economic recovery before it had really got going.  (Mr Carney worked in Japan when interest rates went up “too soon”.  Some believe this killed off an incipient recovery and kept the economy weak throughout the 1990s.)  Adding in his successful Canadian experience with forward guidance in the 2000s, the MPC (endorsed by the Treasury) has adopted “Forward Guidance” as its new policy framework.
Forward Guidance can be summarised as follows:
  1. The Bank expects to maintain its loose money policy as long as the economy has considerable spare capacity, provided this does not risk price or financial stability (see 3 below).
  2. Subject to ‘knockout’ conditions (3 below), the bank will not raise the 0.5% base interest rate and will maintain the asset purchase stock (quantitative easing) until, at least, the headline Labour Force Survey measure of the unemployment rate has fallen to/below a 7% ‘threshold’ (7.8% April-June 2013).
  3. The conditions for this approach, termed ‘knockouts’, are threefold.  It will, at least, consider an adjustment to policy if:
    1. The MPC forecasts the CPI measure of inflation 18-24 months ahead as likely to be 0.5 percentage points above the 2% target (i.e. greater than 2.5%).
    2. Medium term inflationary expectations amongst business, households and financial markets are no longer sufficiently “anchored” i.e. tending to increase.
    3. The Financial Policy Committee (FPC) judges that the monetary policy stance poses a significant threat to financial stability in a way that cannot be contained by other mitigating policies.
It is important to stress that the 2% inflation target still has primacy and any significant risks to this should mean the MPC amends or sets aside the new unemployment test.  Moreover, the ‘knockouts’ are not mandatory.  They are signals for the MPC to consider rather than triggers to necessarily raise interest rates or decrease asset purchases.
What does this mean in practical terms?
  1. Unless the economy accelerates much more than anyone now expects, base interest rates will stay low for the foreseeable future – perhaps, on current forecasts of growth and unemployment, staying at 0.5% until well into 2016/17.  This suggests firms and households can borrow now without worrying that loan costs will rise suddenly.  This should help to sustain the recent improvement in current demand.
  2. Inflation above target will continue to be tolerated as long as the forecast trend is for a move back towards that target within the normal time horizon (3 years).  This carries some inherent concern that there will be too much monetary stimulation over the medium term.
The Bank’s desire to prevent current growth petering out is laudable but there are risks with this approach.
  1. Markets will still speculate.  Every word that the Bank and the MPC use will now be poured over for signals of a change in forward guidance – even if only in nuance.  Market rates will still fluctuate in response to news, rumours and shocks.
  2. The unemployment rate is a lagging indicator.  The recovery will be well underway when it drops below 7%.  This risks that inflation pressures will be building up and interest rates will then have to go higher than might otherwise have been necessary to get inflation back under control.  This might dampen significantly the next economic cycle overall.
  3. Continued asset purchasing is building up a huge money stock that needs to be considered in terms of its inflation potential and what it might mean for the real economy when/if/how its withdrawal occurs.
  4. Savers and investors will suffer lower living standards and be less economically active, constraining real economic activity.  Real growth and low inflation are sustained by productivity gains incentivised by strong real returns over time.  Persistent low interest rates distort such signals.
  5. Moreover, persistent low interest rates mean that debt rebalancing will be less than desired.  Arguably, the housing market and other debt-driven activities need to be more realistic about what ‘normal’ interest rates imply for borrowing costs and loan sustainability over the economic cycle.  The risk is that renewed demand ‘bubbles’ blow up which are only heard when they pop.
All economic policy is about balance.  The MPC has now fixed monetary policy towards the easy end of the monetary ‘seesaw’ for some time to come.  To my mind, this attempt to bolster short-term demand may postpone fundamental rebalancing in the UK economy and risks worse supply adjustments to come.  Unemployment is like a broken leg.  It hurts and debilitates for some considerable time.  But, when it sets and repairs, a full recovery is possible.  Inflation is like a cancer.  It can grow inside the economy for some time before it is recognised.  Its treatment can be awful and ineffective (remember the 1970s/80s).  They are two very different manifestations of the economy.
The MPC’s job is to be pre-emptive: to stop inflation getting a grip on economic decision-making.  The danger of Forward Guidance is that it is reactive.  Waiting for unemployment to fall probably means higher inflation and higher interest rates in the long run than otherwise might have occurred.  Is this a price worth paying for more certainty about short-term growth?
The Bank has allowed inflation to stay above target for four years.  On balance, this was necessary to prevent something worse – depression and deflation.  I do wonder, however, now that confidence is rebuilding, whether the Bank has tied itself to a false premise.  My judgement is that the positive signal of a small increase in interest rates now (perhaps base rates up in four stages to 1.5% by mid-2014) would actually help the recovery, giving savers and investors hope of an earlier ‘return to normal’ and encouraging more current real activity.  This might actually bring unemployment rates below 7% sooner, boosting entrepreneurship towards productive supply without hurting debtors and dampening demand very much – indeed, a necessary part of a rebalanced recovery.
The bottom line for me is that the United Kingdom is not Japan, culturally or economically.  I fear that forward guidance, as currently set out, will be paid for by more of us for longer through higher inflation.  Indeed, it may delay the time that we can say the economy is ‘back to normal’.
Hopefully, I am wrong.  Governor Carney has left himself enough leeway to back away from or amend the unemployment trigger if necessary and he insists that the inflation target remains the MPC’s prime policy driver.  I suspect forward guidance will need to be adjusted from its summer 2013 position over the next few years.
 

 

Friday, 30 November 2012

Post-Keynesian Economics

Post-Keynesian economics[1] is a school of economic thought with its origins in The General Theory of John Maynard Keynes, although its subsequent development was influenced to a large degree by Michał Kalecki, Joan Robinson, Nicholas Kaldor and Paul Davidson. Keynes's biographer Lord Skidelsky writes that the Post Keynesian school has remained closest to the spirit of Keynes's own work.[2][3]

Contents

[hide]

[edit] Introduction

The term post-Keynesian was first used to refer to a distinct school of economic thought by Eichner and Kregel (1975)[4] and by the establishment of the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics in 1978. Prior to 1975, and occasionally in more recent work, Post Keynesian could simply mean economics carried out after 1936, the date of Keynes's The General Theory.[5] Post-Keynesian economists are united in maintaining that Keynes's theory is seriously misrepresented by the two other principal Keynesian schools: neo-Keynesian economics which was orthodox in the 1950s and 60s – and by New Keynesian economics, which together with various strands of neoclassical economics has been dominant in mainstream macroeconomics since the 1980s. Post-Keynesian economics can be seen as an attempt to rebuild economic theory in the light of Keynes's ideas and insights. However even in the early years Post Keynesians such as Joan Robinson sought to distance themselves from Keynes himself and much current post-Keynesian thought cannot be found in Keynes. Some Post Keynesians took an even more progressive view than Keynes with greater emphases on worker friendly policies and re-distribution. Robinson, Paul Davidson and Hyman Minsky were notable for emphasising the effects on the economy of the practical differences between different types of investments in contrast to Keynes more abstract treatment.[6]
The theoretical foundation of post-Keynesian economics is the principle of effective demand, that demand matters in the long as well as the short run, so that a competitive market economy has no natural or automatic tendency towards full employment.[7] Contrary to the views of New Keynesian economists working in the neo-classical tradition, Post-Keynesians do not accept that the theoretical basis of the market failure to provide full employment is rigid or sticky prices or wages. Post-Keynesians typically reject the IS/LM model of John Hicks, which was very influential in neo-Keynesian economics.[citation needed]
The positive contribution of post-Keynesian economics[8] has extended beyond the theory of aggregate employment to theories of income distribution, growth, trade and development in which money demand plays a key role, whereas in neoclassical economics these are determined by the 'real' forces of technology, preferences and endowment. In the field of monetary theory, post-Keynesian economists were among the first to emphasise that the money supply responds to the demand for bank credit,[9] so that the central bank can choose either the quantity of money or the interest rate but not both at the same time. This view has largely been incorporated into monetary policy, which now targets the interest rate as an instrument, rather than the quantity of money. In the field of finance, Hyman Minsky put forward a theory of financial crisis based on financial fragility, which has recently received renewed attention.[10]

[edit] Strands

There are a number of strands to post-Keynesian theory with different emphases. Joan Robinson regarded Michał Kalecki’s theory of effective demand to be superior to Keynes’s theories. Kalecki's theory is based on a class division between workers and capitalists and imperfect competition.[11] She also led the critique of the use of aggregate production functions based on homogeneous capital – the Cambridge capital controversy – winning the argument but not the battle.[12] Much of Nicholas Kaldor’s work was based on the ideas of increasing returns to scale, path dependency, and the key differences between the primary and industrial sectors.[13] Paul Davidson[14] follows Keynes closely in placing time and uncertainty at the centre of theory, from which flow the nature of money and of a monetary economy. Monetary circuit theory, originally developed in continental Europe, places particular emphasis on the distinctive role of money as means of payment. Each of these strands continues to see further development by later generations of economists, although the school of thought has been marginalized within the academic profession.

[edit] Current work

[edit] Journals

Much post-Keynesian research is published in the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics (founded by Sidney Weintraub and Paul Davidson), the Cambridge Journal of Economics, the Review of Political Economy and the Journal of Economic Issues (JEI).

[edit] UK

There is also a UK academic association, the Post Keynesian Economics Study Group (PKSG).

[edit] US

[edit] Kansas City School

In the US, there is a center of Post Keynesian work at the University of Missouri – Kansas City, dubbed "The Kansas City School", together with the Center for Full Employment and Price Stability, which has run a Post Keynesian Conference and Post Keynesian Summer School, together with a group blog, Economic Perspectives from Kansas City. Their research emphasis includes Neo-Chartalism, job guarantee programs, and economic policy.

[edit] Australia

[edit] University of Newcastle

The University of Newcastle, in New South Wales, Australia, houses CofFEE, the Centre of Full Employment and Equity, an active educational, research and collaborative organisation whose focus is on policies "restoring full employment" and achieving an economy that delivers "equitable outcomes for all". CofFEE's work is on Post-Keynesian macroeconomics, labour economics, regional development and monetary economics.

[edit] Major post-Keynesian economists

Major post-Keynesian economists of the first and second generations after Keynes include:

[edit] See also

[edit] Notes

  1. ^ There is semantic dispute as to whether there should be a hyphen between Post and Keynesian, which is symbolic of an intellectual dispute over the nature of the school of thought. The American journal of the same name does not use the hyphen despite its grammatical correctness, and the objection to its use dates partly back to Paul Samuelson's claim to be a post-Keynesian. However Harcourt 2006 uses the hyphen, following Joan Robinson's original use of the phrase. This article standardizes on post-Keynesian for consistency without implying support for Davidson's 'narrow tent' definition of the school of thought – termed Fundamental Keynesian by Lavoie (2005), Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27 (3) 371.
  2. ^ Skidelsky 2009, p. 42
  3. ^ Financial markets, money and the real world, by Paul Davidson, pp. 88–89
  4. ^ Eichner and Kregel 1975
  5. ^ King 2002, p. 10
  6. ^ Hayes 2008
  7. ^ Arestis 1996
  8. ^ For a general introduction see Holt 2001
  9. ^ Kaldor 1980
  10. ^ Minsky 1975
  11. ^ Robinson 1974
  12. ^ Pasinetti 2007
  13. ^ Harcourt 2006, Pasinetti 2007
  14. ^ Davidson 2007

[edit] References

[edit] Further reading

[edit] External links

Friday, 9 November 2012

Quantitative Easing

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia


Jump to: navigation, search

Quantitative easing (QE) is an unconventional monetary policy used by central banks to stimulate the national economy when conventional monetary policy has become ineffective.[1][2] A central bank implements quantitative easing by buying financial assets from commercial banks and other private institutions with newly created money in order to inject a pre-determined quantity of money into the economy. This is distinguished from the more usual policy of buying or selling government bonds to keep market interest rates at a specified target value.[3][4][5][6] Quantitative easing increases the excess reserves of the banks, and raises the prices of the financial assets bought, which lowers their yield.[7]
Expansionary monetary policy typically involves the central bank buying short-term government bonds in order to lower short-term market interest rates.[8][9][10][11] However, when short-term interest rates are either at, or close to, zero, normal monetary policy can no longer lower interest rates. Quantitative easing may then be used by the monetary authorities to further stimulate the economy by purchasing assets of longer maturity than only short-term government bonds, and thereby lowering longer-term interest rates further out on the yield curve.[12][13]
Quantitative easing can be used to help ensure inflation does not fall below target.[6] Risks include the policy being more effective than intended in acting against deflation – leading to higher inflation,[14] or of not being effective enough if banks do not lend out the additional reserves.[15]

[edit] Process

Ordinarily, a central bank conducts monetary policy by raising or lowering its interest rate target for the inter-bank interest rate. A central bank generally achieves its interest rate target mainly through open market operations, where the central bank buys or sells short-term government bonds from banks and other financial institutions.[9][11] When the central bank disburses or collects payment for these bonds, it alters the amount of money in the economy, while simultaneously affecting the price (and thereby the yield) for short-term government bonds. This in turn affects the interbank interest rates.[16][17]
If the nominal interest rate is at or very near zero, the central bank cannot lower it further. Such a situation, called a liquidity trap,[18] can occur, for example, during deflation or when inflation is very low.[19] In such a situation, the central bank may perform quantitative easing by purchasing a pre-determined amount of bonds or other assets from financial institutions without reference to the interest rate.[5][20] The goal of this policy is to increase the money supply rather than to decrease the interest rate, which cannot be decreased further.[21] This is often considered a "last resort" to stimulate the economy.[22][23]
Quantitative easing, and monetary policy in general, can only be carried out if the central bank controls the currency used. The central banks of countries in the Eurozone, for example, cannot unilaterally expand their money supply, and thus cannot employ quantitative easing. They must instead rely on the European Central Bank (ECB) to set monetary policy.[24]

[edit] History

[edit] In Japan

The original Japanese expression for quantitative easing (量的金融緩和, ryōteki kin'yū kanwa), was used for the first time by a Central Bank in the Bank of Japan's publications. The Bank of Japan has claimed that the central bank adopted a policy with this name on 19 March 2001.[25] However, the Bank of Japan's official monetary policy announcement of this date does not make any use of this expression (or any phrase using "quantitative") in either the Japanese original statement or its English translation.[26] Indeed, the Bank of Japan had for years, including as late as February 2001, claimed that "quantitative easing … is not effective" and rejected its use for monetary policy.[27] Speeches by the Bank of Japan leadership in 2001 gradually, and ex post, hardened the subsequent official Bank of Japan stance that the policy adopted by the Bank of Japan on 19 March 2001 was in fact quantitative easing. This became the established official view, especially after Toshihiko Fukui was appointed governor in February 2003. The use by the Bank of Japan is not the origin of the term quantitative easing or its Japanese original (ryoteki kinyu kanwa). This expression had been used since the mid-1990s by critics of the Bank of Japan and its monetary policy.[28]
Quantitative easing was used unsuccessfully by the Bank of Japan (BOJ) to fight domestic deflation in the early 2000s.[12][29][30][31] The Bank of Japan has maintained short-term interest rates at close to zero since 1999. With quantitative easing, it flooded commercial banks with excess liquidity to promote private lending, leaving them with large stocks of excess reserves, and therefore little risk of a liquidity shortage.[32] The BOJ accomplished this by buying more government bonds than would be required to set the interest rate to zero. It also bought asset-backed securities and equities, and extended the terms of its commercial paper purchasing operation.[33]

[edit] After 2007

More recently, similar policies have been used by the United States, the United Kingdom and the Eurozone during the Financial crisis of 2007–2012. Quantitative easing was used by these countries as their risk-free short-term nominal interest rates are either at, or close to, zero. In US, this interest rate is the federal funds rate. In UK, it is the official bank rate.
During the peak of the financial crisis in 2008, in the United States the Federal Reserve expanded its balance sheet dramatically by adding new assets and new liabilities without "sterilizing" these by corresponding subtractions. In the same period the United Kingdom also used quantitative easing as an additional arm of its monetary policy in order to alleviate its financial crisis.[34][35][36]
The European Central Bank has used 12-month and 36-month long term refinancing operations (LTRO) (forms of quantitative easing without referring to them as such[37]) through a process of expanding the assets that banks can use as collateral that can be posted to the ECB in return for euros. This process has led to bonds being "structured for the ECB".[38] By comparison the other central banks were very restrictive in terms of the collateral they accept: the US Federal Reserve used to accept primarily treasuries (in the first half of 2009 it bought almost any relatively safe dollar-denominated securities); the Bank of England applied a large haircut.
During its QE programme, the Bank of England bought gilts from financial institutions, along with a smaller amount of relatively high-quality debt issued by private companies.[21] The banks, insurance companies and pension funds can then use the money they have received for lending or even to buy back more bonds from the bank. The central bank can also lend the new money to private banks or buy assets from banks in exchange for currency.[citation needed] These have the effect of depressing interest yields on government bonds and similar investments, making it cheaper for business to raise capital.[39] Another side effect is that investors will switch to other investments, such as shares, boosting their price and thus encouraging consumption.[21] QE can reduce interbank overnight interest rates, and thereby encourage banks to loan money to higher interest-paying and financially weaker bodies.
Nevin argued that QE failed to stimulate recovery in the UK and instead prolonged the recession between 2009 and 2012 as it caused a collapse in the velocity of circulation, or rate at which money circulates around the economy. This happened because QE drove down gilt yields and annuity rates and forced pensioners, savers and companies to hoard cash to counter the negative impact of QE on their investment income.[40]
In 2012 the Bank of England itself reckoned that quantitative easing had benefited households differently, according to the assets they hold; richer households have more assets.[41].

[edit] Amounts

The US Federal Reserve held between $700 billion and $800 billion of Treasury notes on its balance sheet before the recession. In late November 2008, the Fed started buying $600 billion in Mortgage-backed securities (MBS).[42] By March 2009, it held $1.75 trillion of bank debt, MBS, and Treasury notes, and reached a peak of $2.1 trillion in June 2010. Further purchases were halted as the economy had started to improve, but resumed in August 2010 when the Fed decided the economy was not growing robustly. After the halt in June holdings started falling naturally as debt matured and were projected to fall to $1.7 trillion by 2012. The Fed's revised goal became to keep holdings at the $2.054 trillion level. To maintain that level, the Fed bought $30 billion in 2–10-year Treasury notes a month. In November 2010, the Fed announced a second round of quantitative easing, or "QE2", buying $600 billion of Treasury securities by the end of the second quarter of 2011.[43][44] A third round of quantitative easing, or "QE3," was announced by the Federal Reserve in September 2012. The third round includes a plan to purchase US$40 billion of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) per month. Additionally, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) announced that it would likely maintain the federal funds rate near zero "at least through 2015."[45]
The Bank of England had purchased around £165 billion of assets by September 2009 and around £175 billion of assets by end of October 2010.[46] At its meeting in November 2010, the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) voted to increase total asset purchases to £200 billion. Most of the assets purchased have been UK government securities (gilts), the Bank has also been purchasing smaller quantities of high-quality private sector assets.[47] In December 2010 MPC member Adam Posen called for a £50 billion expansion of the Bank's quantitative easing programme, whilst his colleague Andrew Sentance has called for an increase in interest rates due to inflation being above the target rate of 2%.[48] In October 2011, the Bank of England announced it would undertake another round of QE, creating an additional £75 billion,[49] in February 2012 it announced an additional £50 billion,[50] in July 2012 it announce another £50 billion[51] bringing the total amount to £375 billion. The Bank of England has said that it will not buy more than 70% of any issue of government debt.[52] This means that at least 30% of each issue of government debt will have to be bought by other institutions.
The European Central Bank (ECB) said it would focus efforts on buying covered bonds, a form of corporate debt. It signalled initial purchases would be worth about €60 billion in May 2009. [53]
The Bank of Japan (BOJ) increased the commercial bank current account balance from ¥5 trillion yen to ¥35 trillion (approximately US$300 billion) over a 4-year period starting in March 2001. As well, the BOJ tripled the quantity of long-term Japan government bonds it could purchase on a monthly basis. In early October 2010, the BOJ announced that it would examine the purchase of ¥5 trillion (US$60 billion) in assets. This was an attempt to push the value of the yen versus the US dollar down to stimulate the local economy by making their exports cheaper; it did not work.[54] On 4 August 2011 the bank announced a unilateral move to increase the amount from ¥40 trillion (US$504 billion) to a total of ¥50 trillion (US$630 billion).[55][56] In October 2011 the Bank of Japan expanded its asset purchase program by ¥5 trillion ($66bn) to a total of ¥55 trillion.[57]

[edit] QE1, QE2, and QE3

The expression "QE2" became a "ubiquitous nickname" in 2010, when used to refer to a second round of quantitative easing by central banks in the United States.[58] Retrospectively, the round of quantitative easing preceding QE2 may be called "QE1". Similarly, "QE3" refers to the third round of quantitative easing following QE2.[59][60]
QE3 was announced on 13 September 2012. In an 11-to-1 vote, the Federal Reserve decided to launch a new $40 billion a month, open-ended, bond purchasing program of agency mortgage-backed securities and also to continue extremely low rates policy until at least mid-2015.[61] According to NASDAQ.com, this is effectively a stimulus program which allows the Federal Reserve to relieve $40 billion dollars per month of commercial housing market debt risk with no maximum amount or time limit.[62] Ratings firm Egan-Jones said it believes the Fed’s decision “will hurt the U.S. economy and, by extension, credit quality.” As a result the firm once again slashed the U.S. bond rating bringing it down to AA-. Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke acknowledged concerns about inflation.[63]

[edit] Effectiveness

According to the IMF, the quantitative easing policies undertaken by the central banks of the major developed countries since the beginning of the late-2000s financial crisis have contributed to the reduction in systemic risks following the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. The IMF states that the policies also contributed to the improvements in market confidence and the bottoming out of the recession in the G-7 economies in the second half of 2009.[64]
Economist Martin Feldstein argues that QE2 led to a rise in the stock-market in the second half of 2010, which in turn contributed to increasing consumption and the strong performance of the US economy in late-2010.[65] Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan calculated that as of July 2012 there was "very little impact on the economy" and noted "I'm very surprised at the data."[66]

[edit] Risks

[edit] Adverse impact on savings and pensions

In November 2010, a group of conservative Republican economists and political activists released an open letter to Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke questioning the efficacy of the Fed's QE program. The Fed responded that their actions reflected the economic environment of high unemployment and low inflation.[67]
Lowering interest rates can actually hurt the economy if people who depend on interest income spend less in response to their reduced income. In general, however, the Federal Reserve has assumed that the advantages of the low interest rates outweigh this effect, though they often admit that seniors may be hit as collateral damage.[citation needed]
In the European Union, World Pensions Council (WPC) financial economists have also argued that QE-induced artificially low interest rates will have an adverse impact on the underfunding condition of pension funds as “without returns that outstrip inflation, pension investors face the real value of their savings declining rather than ratcheting up over the next few years”[68]

[edit] Inflation from purchasing liquid assets

Quantitative easing may cause higher inflation than desired if the amount of easing required is overestimated, and too much money is created by the purchase of liquid assets.[14] On the other hand, it can fail if banks remain reluctant to lend money to small business and households in order to spur demand. Quantitative easing can effectively ease the process of deleveraging as it lowers yields.
It should be noted that mortagage-backed securities such as are being purchased as part of the QE3 program are not based on liquid assets, and their purchase does not entail inflation risks. If the easing resulted in an expansion of the money supply, it would be expected to cause an inflationary effect (as indicated by an increase in the annual rate of inflation). Since there is a time lag between money growth and inflation, inflationary pressures associated with money growth from QE could build before the central bank acts to counter them.[69] Inflationary risks are mitigated if the system's economy outgrows the pace of the increase of the money supply from the easing. If production in an economy increases because of the increased money supply, the value of a unit of currency may also increase, even though there is more currency available. For example, if a nation's economy were to spur a significant increase in output at a rate at least as high as the amount of debt monetized, the inflationary pressures would be equalized. This can only happen if member banks actually lend the excess money out instead of hoarding the extra cash. During times of high economic output, the central bank always has the option of restoring the reserves back to higher levels through raising of interest rates or other means, effectively reversing the easing steps taken. Increasing the money supply tends to depreciate a country's exchange rates versus other currencies. This feature of QE directly benefits exporters residing in the country performing QE and also debtors whose debts are denominated in that currency, for as the currency devalues so does the debt. However, it directly harms creditors and holders of the currency as the real value of their holdings decrease. Devaluation of a currency also directly harms importers as the cost of imported goods is inflated by the devaluation of the currency.[70]

[edit] Housing market over-supply and QE3

The only member of the Federal Open Market Committee to vote against QE3, Richmond Federal Reserve Bank President Jeffrey M. Lacker, said:
"The impetus ... is to aid the housing market. That's an area that's fallen short in this recovery. In most other U.S. postwar recoveries, we've seen a pretty sharp snap back in housing. Of course, the reason it hasn't come back in this recovery is that this recession was essentially caused by us building too many houses prior to the recession. We still have a huge overhang of houses that haven't been sold that are vacant. And it's going to take us a while before we want the houses we have, much less need to build more."[71]

[edit] Capital flight

The new money could be used by the banks to invest in emerging markets, commodity-based economies, commodities themselves and non-local opportunities rather than to lend to local businesses that are having difficulty getting loans.[72]

[edit] Comparison with other instruments

[edit] Qualitative easing

Professor Willem Buiter, of the London School of Economics, has proposed a terminology to distinguish quantitative easing, or an expansion of a central bank's balance sheet, from what he terms qualitative easing, or the process of a central bank adding riskier assets onto its balance sheet:
Quantitative easing is an increase in the size of the balance sheet of the central bank through an increase [in its] monetary liabilities (base money), holding constant the composition of its assets. Asset composition can be defined as the proportional shares of the different financial instruments held by the central bank in the total value of its assets. An almost equivalent definition would be that quantitative easing is an increase in the size of the balance sheet of the central bank through an increase in its monetary liabilities that holds constant the (average) liquidity and riskiness of its asset portfolio. Qualitative easing is a shift in the composition of the assets of the central bank towards less liquid and riskier assets, holding constant the size of the balance sheet (and the official policy rate and the rest of the list of usual suspects). The less liquid and more risky assets can be private securities as well as sovereign or sovereign-guaranteed instruments. All forms of risk, including credit risk (default risk) are included.[73]

[edit] Credit easing

In introducing the Federal Reserve's response to the 2008–9 financial crisis, Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke distinguished the new programme, which he termed "credit easing" from Japanese-style quantitative easing. In his speech, he announced:
Our approach—which could be described as "credit easing"—resembles quantitative easing in one respect: It involves an expansion of the central bank's balance sheet. However, in a pure QE regime, the focus of policy is the quantity of bank reserves, which are liabilities of the central bank; the composition of loans and securities on the asset side of the central bank's balance sheet is incidental. Indeed, although the Bank of Japan's policy approach during the QE period was quite multifaceted, the overall stance of its policy was gauged primarily in terms of its target for bank reserves. In contrast, the Federal Reserve's credit easing approach focuses on the mix of loans and securities that it holds and on how this composition of assets affects credit conditions for households and businesses.[74]
Credit easing involves increasing the money supply by the purchase not of government bonds, but of private sector assets such as corporate bonds and residential mortgage-backed securities.[75][76] When undertaking credit easing, the Federal Reserve increases the money supply not by buying government debt, but instead by buying private sector assets including residential mortgage-backed securities.[75][76] In 2010, the Federal Reserve purchased $1.25 trillion of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) in order to support the sagging mortgage market. These purchases increased the monetary base in a way similar to a purchase of government securities.[77]

[edit] Printing money

Quantitative easing has been nicknamed "printing money" by some members of the media,[78][79][80] central bankers,[81] and financial analysts.[82][83] However, central banks state that the use of the newly created money is different in QE. With QE, the newly created money is used for buying government bonds or other financial assets, whereas the term printing money usually implies that the newly minted money is used to directly finance government deficits or pay off government debt (also known as monetizing the government debt).[78]
Central banks in most developed nations (e.g., UK, US, Japan, and EU) are forbidden by law to buy government debt directly from the government and must instead buy it from the secondary market.[77][84] This two-step process, where the government sells bonds to private entities which the central bank then buys, has been called "monetizing the debt" by many analysts.[77] The distinguishing characteristic between QE and monetizing debt is that with QE, the central bank is creating money to stimulate the economy, not to finance government spending. Also, the central bank has the stated intention of reversing the QE when the economy has recovered (by selling the government bonds and other financial assets back into the market).[78] The only effective way to determine whether a central bank has monetized debt is to compare its performance relative to its stated objectives. Many central banks have adopted an inflation target. It is likely that a central bank is monetizing the debt if it continues to buy government debt when inflation is above target, and the government has problems with debt-financing.[77]
Ben Bernanke remarked in 2002 that the US Government had a technology called the printing press, or today its electronic equivalent, so that if rates reached zero and deflation was threatened the government could always act to ensure deflation was prevented. He said, however, that the Government would not print money and distribute it "willy nilly" but would rather focus its efforts in certain areas (for example, buying federal agency debt securities and mortgage-backed securities).[85][86] According to economist Robert McTeer, former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, there is nothing wrong with printing money during a recession, and quantitative easing is different from traditional monetary policy "only in its magnitude and pre-announcement of amount and timing".[87][88] Richard W. Fisher, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, warned that a potential risk of QE is, "the risk of being perceived as embarking on the slippery slope of debt monetization. We know that once a central bank is perceived as targeting government debt yields at a time of persistent budget deficits, concern about debt monetization quickly arises." and later in the same speech states that the Fed is monetizing the government debt, "The math of this new exercise is readily transparent: The Federal Reserve will buy $110 billion a month in Treasuries, an amount that, annualized, represents the projected deficit of the federal government for next year. For the next eight months, the nation’s central bank will be monetizing the federal debt."[89]

[edit] Altering debt maturity structure

Based on research reassessing the effectiveness of the US Federal Open Market Committee action in 1961 known as Operation Twist, The Economist, based on research by economist Eric Swanson, has posited that a similar restructuring of the supply of different types of debt would have an effect equal to that of QE.[90] Such action would allow finance ministries (e.g., the US Department of the Treasury) a role in the process now reserved for central banks.[90]

[edit] See also

[edit] References

  1. ^ "Loose thinking". The Economist. 15 October 2009. http://www.economist.com/node/14649284. 
  2. ^ Publications | Learning the Lessons from QE and Other Unconventional Monetary Policies: 17–18 November. Bank of England (18 November 2011).
  3. ^ Quantitative Easing Explained. London: Bank of England. 2011. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/pdf/qe-pamphlet.pdf. "The MPC's decision to inject money directly into the economy does not involve printing more banknotes. Instead, the Bank buys assets from private sector institutions – that could be insurance companies, pension funds, banks or non-financial firms – and credits the seller's bank account." 
  4. ^ "Quantitative Easing". Bank of England. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/quarterlybulletin/qb090201.pdf. "The Bank can create new money electronically by increasing the balance on a reserve account. So when the Bank purchases an asset from a bank, for example, it simply credits that bank's reserve account with the additional funds. This generates an expansion in the supply of central bank money" 
  5. ^ a b "Q&A: Quantitative easing". BBC. 9 March 2009. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7924506.stm. Retrieved 29 March 2009. 
  6. ^ a b "Quantitative Easing Explained". Bank of England. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/assetpurchases.htm. "This does not involve printing more banknotes. Instead the Bank pays for these assets by creating money electronically and crediting the accounts of the companies it bought the assets from." 
  7. ^ Elliott, Larry (8 January 2009). "Guardian Business Glossary: Quantitative Easing". The Guardian (London). http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2008/oct/14/businessglossary. Retrieved 19 January 2009. 
  8. ^ Open market operations: A Glossary of Political Economy Terms – Dr. Paul M. Johnson. Auburn.edu.
  9. ^ a b Open Market Operation – Fedpoints. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
  10. ^ Monetary policy Instruments. Swiss National Bank.
  11. ^ a b The implementation of monetary policy in the euro area. European Central Bank. 2008. pp. 14–19. 
  12. ^ a b "Dr. Econ: I noticed that banks have dramatically increased their excess reserve holdings. Is this buildup of reserves related to monetary policy?". Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. March 2010. http://www.frbsf.org/education/activities/drecon/2010/0310.html. Retrieved 4 April 2011. 
  13. ^ Bernanke, Ben (13 January 2009). "The Crisis and the Policy Response". Federal Reserve. http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090113a.htm. Retrieved 4 April 2011. 
  14. ^ a b Bowlby, Chris (5 March 2009). "The fear of printing too much money". BBC News. http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/7925981.stm. Retrieved 25 June 2011. 
  15. ^ Isidore, Chris (5 October 2010). "Federal Reserve move toward quantitative easing poses risks". CNNMoney.com. http://money.cnn.com/2010/10/05/news/economy/Fed_quantitative_easing/index.htm. Retrieved 25 June 2011. 
  16. ^ Abel, Andrew; Bernanke, Ben (2005), "14.1", Macroeconomics (5th ed.), Pearson, pp. 522–532 
  17. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002), "Chapter 18: Money Supply and Money Demand", Macroeconomics (5th ed.), Worth, pp. 482–489 
  18. ^ Eggertsson, Gauti. "The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics". http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/economists/eggertsson/palgrave.pdf. 
  19. ^ Billi, Roberto M.; Kahn, George A. (2008). "What is the optimal inflation rate?". Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review (2). http://www.kansascityfed.org/Publicat/ECONREV/PDF/2q08billi_kahn.pdf. 
  20. ^ Bullard, James (Jan 2010). "Quantitative easing—uncharted waters for monetary policy". Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. http://stlouisfed.org/publications/re/articles/?id=1862. Retrieved 26 July 2011. 
  21. ^ a b c Quantitative Easing explained. Bank of England. pp. 7–9. ISBN 1-85730-114-5. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/pdf/qe-pamphlet.pdf. Retrieved 20 July 2010. "(page 7) Bank buys assets from … institutions … credits the seller's bank account. So the seller has more money in their bank account, while their bank holds a corresponding claim against the Bank of England (known as reserves … (page 8) high-quality debt … (page 9) … such as shares or company bonds. That will push up the prices of those assets," 
  22. ^ "Quantitative easing: A therapy of last resort". The New York Times. 1 January 2009. http://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/11/business/worldbusiness/11iht-views12.1.19248009.html. Retrieved 12 July 2010. 
  23. ^ Stewart, Heather (29 January 2009). "Quantitative easing: last resort to get credit moving again". The Guardian (London). http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2009/jan/29/question-and-answer-quantitative-easing. Retrieved 12 July 2010. 
  24. ^ "Protocol on the Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank: statements 14.4, 18.2". pp. 5–6. http://www.ecb.int/ecb/legal/pdf/en_statute_2.pdf. Retrieved 7 April 2011. 
  25. ^ Shirakawa, Masaaki, "One Year Under 'Quantitative Easing'", Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, 2002.
  26. ^ Bank of Japan, New Procedures for Money Market Operations and Monetary Easing, 19 March 2001. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  27. ^ Hiroshi Fujiki et. al., Monetary Policy under Zero Interest Rate: Viewpoints of Central Bank Economists, Monetary and Economic Studies, February 2001, p.98. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  28. ^ First in the headline of Richard Werner's article in the Nikkei, the main Japanese financial daily newspaper: Richard Werner (1995), "Keizai Kyoshitsu: Keiki kaifuku, ryoteiki kinyu kanwa kara," Nikkei, 2 September 1995, p. 26
  29. ^ "Japan sets inflation goal in fight against deflation". BBC News. 16 February 2010. http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/8517760.stm. Retrieved 4 April 2011. 
  30. ^ Mark Spiegel. "FRBSF: Economic Letter—Quantitative Easing by the Bank of Japan (11/02/2001)". Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2001/el2001-31.html. Retrieved 19 January 2009. 
  31. ^ Voutsinas, Konstantinos, and Richard A. Werner, "New Evidence on the Effectiveness of 'Quantitative Easing' in Japan", Centre for Banking, Finance and Sustainable Development, School of Management, University of Southampton.
  32. ^ Easing Out of the Bank of Japan's Monetary Easing Policy (2004–33, 19 November 2004). Frbsf.org.
  33. ^ PIMCO/Tomoya Masanao interview[dead link]
  34. ^ Alloway, Tracy, The Unthinkable Has Happened, ft.com, 10 November 2008. Retrieved 9 August 2010.
  35. ^ 'Bernanke-san' Signals Policy Shift, Evoking Japan Comparison, Bloomberg.com, 2 December 2008
  36. ^ Bank pumps £75bn into economy, ft.com, 5 March 2009
  37. ^ Lynn, Matthew, "What central banks provide, oil markets take away", MarketWatch, 29 February 2012. Retrieved 29 February 2012.
  38. ^ Evans, Rachel, Unsellable bonds structured to abuse ECB scheme, IFLR, 2 February 2009
  39. ^ Bean, Charles (July 2009). "Ask the Deputy Governor". Bank of England. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/qe/askqa.htm. Retrieved 12 July 2010. 
  40. ^ Nevin, Michael (2012). The Golden Guinea. The International Financial Crisis, 2007–2014: Causes, Consequences and Cures. Southdown Books. p. 281. ISBN 978-0-85730-103-1. 
  41. ^ The Distributional Effects of Asset Purchases, Bank of England, July 2012
  42. ^ Harding, Robin. (3 November 2010) Quantitative easing explained. Financial Times.
  43. ^ Censky, Annalyn (3 November 2010). "QE2: Fed pulls the trigger". CNNmoney.com. http://money.cnn.com/2010/11/03/news/economy/fed_decision/index.htm. Retrieved 10 August 2011. 
  44. ^ What is the Federal Reserve Quantitative Easing. Useconomy.about.com (22 September 2011).
  45. ^ Zumbrun, Joshua (13 September 2012). "Fed Undertakes QE3 With $40 Billion MBS Purchases Per Month". Bloomberg News. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-09-13/fed-plans-to-buy-40-billion-in-mortgage-securities-each-month.html. Retrieved 13 September 2012. 
  46. ^ http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2009/speech404.pdf
  47. ^ [1][dead link]
  48. ^ Arnott, Sarah (23 December 2010). "Downward revision for third-quarter growth". The Independent (London). http://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/news/downward-revision-for-thirdquarter-growth-2167438.html. 
  49. ^ "Bank of England injects further £75bn into economy". BBC News. 6 October 2011. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-15196078. 
  50. ^ "Bank of England injects another £50bn into UK economy". BBC News. 9 February 2012. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-16963116. 
  51. ^ Publications | Bank of England maintains Bank Rate at 0.5% and increases size of Asset Purchase Programme by £50 billion to £375 billion. Bank of England.
  52. ^ "A flat economy (cont'd)". BBC News. 12 January 2012. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-16538773. 
  53. ^ Duncan, Gary (8 May 2009). "European Central Bank opts for quantitative easing to lift the eurozone". The Times (London). http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/economics/article6244869.ece. 
  54. ^ Quantitative Easing – A lesson learned from Japan. Oye Times.
  55. ^ "Japan government and central bank intervene to cut yen". BBC News. 4 August 2011. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-14398392. 
  56. ^ Bank of Japan increases QE by 10 trillion yen. Banking Times (4 August 2011).
  57. ^ "Bank of Japan increases stimulus and keeps rates low". BBC News. 27 October 2011. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-15472839. 
  58. ^ Fed's desperate measure is a watershed moment, John Authers, The Long View, Financial Times, 5 November 2010
  59. ^ Conerly, Bill (13 September 2012). "QE3 and the Economy: It Will Help, But Not Solve All Problems". Forbes. http://www.forbes.com/sites/billconerly/2012/09/13/qe3-and-the-economy-it-will-help-but-not-solve-all-problems/. Retrieved 13 September 2012. 
  60. ^ Inman, Phillip (14 July 2011). "Moody's sounds note of caution while Bernanke promises support for US economy". The Guardian (London). http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2011/jul/13/bernanke-ready-for-more-quantitative-easing. Retrieved 19 July 2011. 
  61. ^ Goldstein, Steve (13 September 2012). "Fed To Launch QE3 Of $40 Billion MBS Each Month". http://www.foxbusiness.com/markets/2012/09/13/fed-to-launch-qe3-40-billion-mbs-each-month/. Retrieved 19 September 2012. 
  62. ^ Jensen, Greg (19 September 2012). "QE3 Launched: The Ever Decreasing Effects of Monetary Stimulus". http://community.nasdaq.com/News/2012-09/qe3-launched-the-ever-decreasing-effects-of-monetary-stimulus.aspx?storyid=174677. Retrieved 19 September 2012. 
  63. ^ Egan, Matt (14 September 2012). "QE3 Sparks U.S. Credit Ratings Downgrade From Egan-Jones". http://www.foxbusiness.com/government/2012/09/14/fearing-qe3-egan-jones-downgrades-us-again/. Retrieved 19 September 2012. 
  64. ^ Unconventional Choices for Unconventional Times: Credit and Quantitative Easing in Advanced Economies; by Vladimir Klyuev, Phil de Imus, and Krishna Srinivasan; IMF Staff Position Note SPN/09/27; November 4, 2009.. (PDF).
  65. ^ Feldstein, Martin (24 February 2011). "Quantitative Easing and America's Economic Rebound". project-syndicate.org. Project Syndicate. http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/feldstein33/English. Retrieved 4 April 2011. 
  66. ^ Navarro, Bruno J.. (12 July 2012) CNBC coverage of Greenspan. Finance.yahoo.com.
  67. ^ "Open letter to Ben Bernanke". The Wall Street Journal. 15 November 2010. http://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2010/11/15/open-letter-to-ben-bernanke/. Retrieved 9 October 2011. 
  68. ^ M. Nicolas J. Firzli quoted in Sinead Cruise (4 August 2012). "‘Zero Return World Squeezes Retirement Plans’". Reuters with CNBC (.). http://www.cnbc.com/id/48484139. Retrieved 5 Aug 2012. 
  69. ^ Thornton, Daniel L. (2010). "The downside of quantitative easing". Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses (34). http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/10/ES1034.pdf. 
  70. ^ Inman, Phillip (29 June 2011). "How the world paid the hidden cost of America's quantitative easing". The Guardian (London). http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2011/jun/29/how-world-paid-hidden-cost-america-quantitative-easing. 
  71. ^ National Public Radio (September 15, 2012) "Fed's Latest Stimulus Lacked Unanimous Support" All Things Considered
  72. ^ Lynch, David J. (17 November 2010). "Bernanke's 'Cheap Money' Stimulus Spurs Corporate Investment Outside U.S". Bloomberg. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-11-17/bernanke-s-cheap-money-stimulus-spurs-corporate-investment-outside-u-s-.html. 
  73. ^ Willem Buiter (9 December 2008). "Quantitative easing and qualitative easing: a terminological and taxonomic proposal". http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2008/12/quantitative-easing-and-qualitative-easing-a-terminological-and-taxonomic-proposal/. Retrieved 2009-02-02. 
  74. ^ Credit Easing versus Quantitative Easing. Federalreserve.gov (13 January 2009).
  75. ^ a b Credit Easing Definition. Financial Times Lexicon.
  76. ^ a b How Bernanke's Policy of 'Credit Easing' Works. BusinessWeek (28 January 2009).
  77. ^ a b c d http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/10/ES1014.pdf
  78. ^ a b c Stephanomics: Is quantitative easing really just printing money?. BBC.
  79. ^ Mackintosh, James. (2 December 2010) QE: Replacement not debasement. FT.com.
  80. ^ Hyde, Deborah. (8 November 2010) Ask Citywire: Quantitative easing part II – Citywire Money. Citywire.co.uk.
  81. ^ Bullard, James (30 June 2009). Exit Strategies for the Federal Reserve (Speech). Global Interdependence Center, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, United States. 
  82. ^ "Bank of England to create new money: a Q&A". The Daily Telegraph (London). 5 March 2009. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/financetopics/recession/4941631/Bank-of-England-to-creating-new-money-a-QandA.html. 
  83. ^ Duncan, Gary (5 March 2009). "Bank should start printing money says Times MPC". The Times (London). http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/economics/the_times_mpc/article5847958.ece. 
  84. ^ Stephanomics. BBC.
  85. ^ Wolf, Martin. (16 December 2008) "‘Helicopter Ben’ confronts the challenge of a lifetime". Financial Times.
  86. ^ Speech, Bernanke -Deflation- November 21, 2002. Federal Reserve Bank.
  87. ^ McTeer, Bob (23 December 2010). "There's nothing wrong with the Fed printing money". Forbes. http://blogs.forbes.com/beltway/2010/12/23/theres-nothing-wrong-with-the-fed-printing-money/. 
  88. ^ McTeer, Bob (26 August 2010). "Quantitative easing is a toxic phrase for a routine policy". Forbes. http://blogs.forbes.com/beltway/2010/08/26/quantitative-easing-is-a-toxic-phrase-for-a-routine-policy/. 
  89. ^ Speeches by Richard W. Fisher. Dallas Fed (8 November 2010).
  90. ^ a b "Twisted thinking: Government Debt-Managers May be Undermining Quantitative Easing". The Economist. 31 March 2011. http://www.economist.com/node/18486271?story_id=18486271. Retrieved 10 April 2011. 

[edit] External links



The Blogger Ref Link http://www.p2pfoundation.net/Transfinancial_Economics